BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £1, it will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
England and Wales Court of Appeal (Civil Division) Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> England and Wales Court of Appeal (Civil Division) Decisions >> Bookmakers' Afternoon Greyhound Services Ltd & Ors v Amalgamated Racing Ltd & Ors [2009] EWCA Civ 750 (28 July 2009) URL: http://www.bailii.org/ew/cases/EWCA/Civ/2009/750.html Cite as: [2009] EWCA Civ 750, [2009] UKCLR 863 |
[New search] [Printable RTF version] [Help]
COURT OF APPEAL (CIVIL DIVISION)
ON APPEAL FROM THE HIGH COURT OF JUSTICE
CHANCERY DIVISION
MR JUSTICE MORGAN
Strand, London, WC2A 2LL |
||
B e f o r e :
LORD JUSTICE LLOYD
and
LORD JUSTICE MOORE-BICK
____________________
(1) BOOKMAKERS' AFTERNOON GREYHOUND SERVICES LTD (2) LADBROKES BETTING AND GAMING LTD (3) WILLIAM HILL ORGANIZATION LTD |
Claimants Appellants |
|
- and - |
||
(1) AMALGAMATED RACING LTD (2) RACING UK LTD (3) ALPHAMERIC PLC (4) ALPHAMERIC GAMING LTD (5) RACECOURSE MEDIA SERVICES LTD (6) RACECOURSE INVESTMENTS LTD (7) THE WESTERN MEETING CLUB LTD (8) BANGOR-ON-DEE RACES LTD (9) THE BEVERLEY RACE CO LTD (10) CARTMEL STEEPLECHASES (HOLKER) LTD (11) THE CATTERICK RACECOURSE CO LTD (12) THE CHESTER RACE CO LTD (13) GOODWOOD RACECOURSE LTD (14) THE HAMILTON PARK RACECOURSE CO LTD (15) THE LUDLOW RACE CLUB LTD (16) MUSSELBURGH RACECOURSE CO LTD (17) NEWBURY RACECOURSE PLC (18) THE PONTEFRACT PARK RACE CO LTD (19) REDCAR RACECOURSE LTD (20) THE BIBURY CLUB LTD (21) THIRSK RACECOURSE LTD (22) WETHERBY STEEPLECHASE COMMITTEE LTD (23) YORK RACECOURSE LTD |
Defendants Respondents |
____________________
WordWave International Limited
A Merrill Communications Company
165 Fleet Street, London EC4A 2DY
Tel No: 020 7404 1400, Fax No: 020 7404 1424
Official Shorthand Writers to the Court)
(instructed by SJ Berwin LLP) for the Appellants
Peter Roth Q.C., Paul Harris and Ronit Kreisberger
(instructed by Wiggin LLP) for the Respondents
Hearing dates: 12-14 May 2009
____________________
Crown Copyright ©
Lord Justice Lloyd:
Introduction
The parties to the proceedings
British racecourses
i) The Jockey Club courses are Aintree, Carlisle, Cheltenham, Epsom, Exeter, Haydock Park, Huntingdon, Kempton Park, Market Rasen, Newmarket, Nottingham, Sandown Park, Warwick and Wincanton.ii) Within the RUK group there are also the Large Independent courses, namely Ayr, Chester, Goodwood, Newbury and York.
iii) The other, smaller independent courses within the RUK group are Bangor-on-Dee, Beverley, Cartmel, Catterick, Hamilton Park, Ludlow, Musselburgh, Pontefract, Redcar, Salisbury, Thirsk and Wetherby.
i) The Northern racecourses are those operated by Northern Racing Ltd. There were 8 of them when they granted exclusive LBO media rights to BAGS: Bath, Brighton, Chepstow, Fontwell Park, Great Yarmouth, Hereford, Newcastle and Uttoxeter. Since then Sedgefield has become a Northern course; it had granted exclusive rights to SIS.ii) The Arena courses are those operated by Arena Leisure plc: Doncaster, Folkestone, Lingfield Park, Royal Windsor, Southwell, Wolverhampton and Worcester.
iii) The former GG Media courses were originally Exeter, Fakenham, Hexham, Leicester, Perth, Sedgefield, Stratford, Taunton, Kelso and Towcester. Exeter is now a Jockey Club course; Sedgefield is a Northern course and Towcester has left the group as well. The group of 8 of these including Exeter but not Sedgefield or Towcester is sometimes called the ICAC courses.
i) Ascot, which is independent but followed the RUK courses in granting exclusive rights to AMRAC;ii) Newton Abbot, Plumpton, Ripon and Towcester, each of which independently granted exclusive rights to SIS.
Article 81 of the EU Treaty
"The following shall be prohibited as incompatible with the common market: all agreements between undertakings, decisions by associations of undertakings and concerted practices which may affect trade between Member States and which have as their object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition within the common market, and in particular those which:
a) directly or indirectly fix purchase or selling prices or any other trading conditions;
b) limit or control production, markets, technical development, or investment;
c) share markets or sources of supply;
d) apply dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties, thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage;
e) make the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by the other parties of supplementary obligations which, by their nature or according to commercial usage, have no connection with the subject of such contracts."
"Any agreements or decisions prohibited pursuant to this Article shall be automatically void."
That provision is relevant to one of the issues on the appeal.
"The provisions of paragraph 1 may, however, may be declared inapplicable in the case of:
- any agreement or category of agreements between undertakings;
- any decision or category of decisions by associations of undertakings;
- any concerted practice or category of concerted practices,
which contributes to improving the production or distribution of goods or to promoting technical or economic progress, while allowing consumers a fair share of the resulting benefit, and which does not:
a) impose on the undertakings concerned restrictions which are not indispensable to the attainment of these objectives;
b) afford such undertakings the possibility of eliminating competition in respect of a substantial part of the products in question."
The issues on the appeal
i) First, the Claimants contend that the relevant arrangements had as their object the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition within the market. They rely on two aspects: first, that the RUK courses agreed upon minimum prices for the grant of LBO media rights to AMRAC; secondly, that they agreed on closed dealing with AMRAC, that is to say they locked SIS and BAGS out of the negotiations.ii) Alternatively, they contend that the arrangements had as their effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition within the market. They rely on the two points mentioned above and also on a third, namely that the racecourses undertook collective instead of individual negotiation with AMRAC. At trial it was also contended that the grant of exclusive rights to AMRAC was in breach of the article, but that is no longer pursued.
iii) An issue relevant at least to the point about collective selling as an anti-competitive effect is whether the RUK courses were competitors with each other in the relevant respects. The judge held that they were, but this is challenged by a Respondent's Notice.
iv) The Defendants succeeded in defeating both the object and the effect challenges. One of their principal arguments can be referred to as objective necessity, namely that the arrangements were objectively necessary for the pro-competitive object of ensuring entry by a new undertaking into a market previously monopolised by one operator.
v) Lastly, if the appeal succeeds on other points, and subject to any determination of the issues under article 81(3), so that the arrangements between the RUK courses did infringe article 81, the Appellants contend that this of itself renders the licences granted by each undertaking to AMRAC void under article 81(2). That, too, is in dispute.
Outline history leading to the AMRAC licences
The joint venture agreement
The AMRAC licences
"ARL undertakes that, without prejudice to clause 2.3 below, it will not before or during the Term contract with any British Racecourses who are Founder Members for the licensing of rights in the nature of the LBO Rights for any period during the Term except on terms which are identical to those set out in this licence and, if it seeks to offer any variation of such terms to any other Founder Member will obtain the prior written consent of the RMS Board (not to be unreasonably withheld or delayed) to such offer to any other Founder Member."
The economic context
The Appellants' case as to anti-competitive agreements
Were the RUK racecourses in competition with each other?
"This means the third parties only have one single source of supply. Third-party commercial operators are therefore forced to purchase the relevant rights under the conditions jointly determined in the context of the invitation to bid, which is issued by the joint selling body. This means that the joint selling body restricts competition in the sense that it determines prices and all other trading conditions on behalf of all individual football clubs producing the UEFA Champions League content. In the absence of the joint selling agreement the football clubs would set such prices and conditions independently of one another and in competition with one another. The reduction in competition caused by the joint selling agreement therefore leads to uniform prices compared to a situation with individual selling."
"The Commission further considered the question of competition in the context of the special characteristics of sport. At paragraph 125, it noted UEFA's submission that football clubs were not truly independent competitors. At paragraph 128, the Commission held that UEFA and the football clubs were economic competitors in selling commercial rights (property rights and media rights) to football matches. If there were no joint selling arrangement then these parties would be selling their rights individually and in competition with one another. At paragraph 129, the Commission again stated that the clubs were economic competitors in relation to the sale of the relevant rights."
"In my judgment, that reasoning applies in this case. Although racecourses do not compete with each other in a number of respects and for a number of reasons, it is open to them to compete with each other when it comes to selling their LBO media rights."
"The specific point being addressed in those comments is not wholly clear and the reasoning is very brief. In my judgment, the reasoning in the UEFA case is clear and intelligible and applicable to this case. Accordingly, I hold that the racecourses are potentially in competition with each other in relation to the sale of their LBO media rights."
Arrangements with the object of restricting competition
"From its wording it is clear that the notion of restriction of competition by object refers primarily to the object of the agreement. The Community judicature has found an anti-competitive aim or tendency of an agreement to exist in particular where the necessary consequence of the agreement was the restriction of competition. In such a case in principle the parties may not argue that they did not intend any restriction of competition or that their agreement also pursued a different aim."
"In fact, to determine whether an agreement comes within the prohibition laid down in Article 81(1) EC, close regard must be paid to the wording of its provisions and to the objectives which it is intended to attain. In that regard, even supposing it to be established that the parties to an agreement acted without any subjective intention of restricting competition, but with the object of remedying the effects of a crisis in their sector, such considerations are irrelevant for the purposes of applying that provision. Indeed, an agreement may be regarded as having a restrictive object even if it does not have the restriction of competition as its sole aim but also pursues other legitimate objectives (General Motors v Commission, paragraph 64 and the case-law cited). It is only in connection with Article 81(3) EC that matters such as those relied upon by BIDS may, if appropriate, be taken into consideration for the purposes of obtaining an exemption from the prohibition laid down in Article 81(1) EC."
"33. The BIDS arrangements are intended therefore, essentially, to enable several undertakings to implement a common policy which has as its object the encouragement of some of them to withdraw from the market and the reduction, as a consequence, of the overcapacity which affects their profitability by preventing them from achieving economies of scale.
34. That type of arrangement conflicts patently with the concept inherent in the EC Treaty provisions relating to competition, according to which each economic operator must determine independently the policy which it intends to adopt on the common market. Article 81(1) EC is intended to prohibit any form of coordination which deliberately substitutes practical cooperation between undertakings for the risks of competition.
35. In the context of competition, the undertakings which signed the BIDS arrangements would have, without such arrangements, no means of improving their profitability other than by intensifying their commercial rivalry or resorting to concentrations. With the BIDS arrangements it would be possible for them to avoid such a process and to share a large part of the costs involved in increasing the degree of market concentration as a result, in particular, of the levy of €2 per head processed by each of the stayers.
36. In addition, the means put in place to attain the objective of the BIDS arrangements include restrictions whose object is anti-competitive."
"The second category concerns cases in which an agreement is ambivalent in terms of its effects on competition. If the object of an agreement is to promote competition, for example by strengthening competition on a market, opening up a market or allowing a new competitor access to a market, the necessary restriction of the requirement of independence can, when matters are viewed as a whole, give way to the aim of promoting competition."
"Some categories of agreements do not fall under article 81(1) because of their very nature. This is normally true for cooperation that does not imply a coordination of the parties' competitive behaviours in the market, such as:
- cooperation between non-competitors
- cooperation between competing companies that cannot independently carry out the project or activity covered by the cooperation."
Arrangements with the effect of restricting competition
"68. Moreover, in a case such as this, where it is accepted that the agreement does not have as its object a restriction of competition, the effects of the agreement should be considered and for it to be caught by the prohibition it is necessary to find that those factors are present which show that competition has in fact been prevented or restricted or distorted to an appreciable extent. The competition in question must be understood within the actual context in which it would occur in the absence of the agreement in dispute; the interference with competition may in particular be doubted if the agreement seems really necessary for the penetration of a new area by an undertaking (Société Technique et Minière Case 56/65, [1966] ECR 235, at 249-250).
…
71. The examination required in the light of Article 81(1) EC consists essentially in taking account of the impact of the agreement on existing and potential competition (see, to that effect, Case C-234/89 Delimitis [1991] ECR I-935, paragraph 21) and the competition situation in the absence of the agreement (Société Technique et Minière at 249-250), those two factors being intrinsically linked.
72. The examination of competition in the absence of an agreement appears to be particularly necessary as regards markets undergoing liberalisation or emerging markets, as in the case of the 3G mobile communications market here at issue, where effective competition may be problematic owing, for example, to the presence of a dominant operator, the concentrated nature of the market structure or the existence of significant barriers to entry - factors referred to, in the present case, in the Decision."
"cooperation between firms which compete on markets closely related to the market directly concerned by the cooperation cannot be defined as restricting competition, if the cooperation is the only commercially justifiable possible way to enter a new market, to launch a new product or service or to carry out a specific project."
"The primary consideration in this case was that the 18 operators of the 30 courses wanted to create a joint venture and to sponsor the entry of that joint venture into the market to provide competition for the purchase of their rights. The suggested alternative to that would be to sell those rights to the incumbent. That would undermine the joint venture and imperil its entry. It would not be logical to promote the joint venture and then to withhold from it the rights which it needed and wished to have to enter the market. There is not a true comparison between granting LBO media rights to BAGS and granting LBO media rights to AMRAC. A deal with BAGS would not result in the existence of competition in the market, would not result in the successful entry of the joint venture and would not result in participation in a successful joint venture. If the two deals are not alike, then in my judgment, it is not anti-competitive for an operator to decide which type of deal he prefers to pursue and then not to deal on an alternative and incompatible basis."
Objective necessity
"It is not strictly necessary therefore to consider whether any restriction on competition, resulting from collective negotiation, was objectively necessary. If I had to decide that question I would unhesitatingly hold that it was objectively necessary. It must be remembered that AMRAC was a joint venture in which the operators of the racecourses were participating. The participants necessarily had to talk to each other and negotiate collectively in order to create the joint venture. It was up to them to decide between themselves as to the terms on which they should participate in the joint venture. They were entitled to decide that they would share the total price for the LBO rights on equivalent terms and that their different interests would be reflected in the dividends payable out of profits."
"107. As regards the objective necessity of a restriction, it must be observed that inasmuch as, as has been shown in paragraph 72 et seq. above, the existence of a rule of reason in Community competition law cannot be upheld, it would be wrong, when classifying ancillary restrictions, to interpret the requirement for objective necessity as implying a need to weigh the pro and anti-competitive effects of an agreement. Such an analysis can take place only in the specific framework of Article 85(3) of the Treaty.
108. That approach is justified not merely so as to preserve the effectiveness of Article 85(3) of the Treaty, but also on grounds of consistency. As Article 85(1) of the Treaty does not require an analysis of the positive and negative effects on competition of a principal restriction, the same finding is necessary with regard to the analysis of accompanying restrictions.
109. Consequently, as the Commission has correctly asserted, examination of the objective necessity of a restriction in relation to the main operation cannot but be relatively abstract. It is not a question of analysing whether, in the light of the competitive situation on the relevant market, the restriction is indispensable to the commercial success of the main operation but of determining whether, in the specific context of the main operation, the restriction is necessary to implement that operation. If, without the restriction, the main operation is difficult or even impossible to implement, the restriction may be regarded as objectively necessary for its implementation."
"We confess to some difficulty in reconciling the approach of the ECJ in Gøttrup-Klim and Wouters with that of the CFI in Métropole, but find it unnecessary to dwell on the explanation in Métropole as to the rationale that the CFI perceived as underlying cases such as Gøttrup-Klim and Wouters (the latter of course being decided after Métropole). We consider that these two decisions of the ECJ show that the assessment of whether or not a particular arrangement constitutes an infringement of Article 85(1) (now Article 81(1)), or therefore of the Chapter I prohibition, is a rather more flexible exercise than the CFI was perhaps willing to appreciate. It is not enough that the arrangement is apparently anti-competitive, as in Gøttrup-Klim and Wouters. What those cases show is that ostensibly restrictive arrangements which are necessary to achieve a proper commercial objective will not, or may not, constitute an anti-competitive infringement at all. Whether or not they will do so requires an objective analysis of the particular arrangement entered into by the parties, assessed by reference to their subjective "wants" and against the evidence of the particular market in which they made their arrangement. The task then is to consider whether the restrictive arrangement of which complaint is made is "necessary" to achieve the objective. The RCA appellants also submitted that the concept of "necessity" in this context is not an absolute one, but has an element of flexibility about it, for which they referred us to paragraph 109 in the Métropole case in which the course observed that "If, without the restriction, the main operation is difficult or even impossible to implement, the restriction may be regarded as objectively necessary for its implementation." We also accept this last submission: competition law is not an area of law in which there is much scope for absolute concepts or sharp edges."
Are the AMRAC licences void by reason of article 81(2)?
"If the facts of a particular case led to that conclusion then both the horizontal parties and the person taking the supply from one of them could be held to be party to an agreement and, if that agreement infringed Article 81(1), then that agreement is void under Article 81(2). In such a case, the consequence would be that the party taking a supply from the horizontal parties would not acquire rights under the offending agreement (or the offending part of it)."
Lord Justice Moore-Bick
Lord Justice Mummery