BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £1, it will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
England and Wales Court of Appeal (Civil Division) Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> England and Wales Court of Appeal (Civil Division) Decisions >> Everything Everywhere Ltd v Competition Commission & Ors [2013] EWCA Civ 154 (06 March 2013) URL: http://www.bailii.org/ew/cases/EWCA/Civ/2013/154.html Cite as: [2013] EWCA Civ 154 |
[New search] [Printable RTF version] [Help]
ON APPEAL FROM THE COMPETITION APPEAL TRIBUNAL
Marcus Smith QC, Brian Landers and Professor Colin Mayer
[2012] CAT 11
Strand, London, WC2A 2LL |
||
B e f o r e :
LORD JUSTICE MOSES
and
LORD JUSTICE PATTEN
____________________
Everything Everywhere Limited |
Appellant |
|
- and - |
||
Competition Commission Office of Communications Hutchison 3G (UK) Limited British Telecommunications plc |
1st Respondent 2nd Respondent 3rd Respondent 4th Respondent |
____________________
Mr Michael Bowsher QC and Mr Nicholas Gibson (instructed by the Treasury Solicitor) for the 1st Respondent, Mr Josh Holmes and Mr Mark Vinall (instructed by Ofcom) for the 2nd Respondent, Mr Brian Kennelly and Ms Jessica Boyd (instructed by Baker & McKenzie LLP) for the 3rd Respondent, Mr Robert Palmer (instructed by BT Legal) for the 4th Respondent
Hearing dates: 28th-30th January, 2013
____________________
Crown Copyright ©
Lord Justice Moses :
"Whether the charge controls imposed…[in the Annex to the Decision]…have been set at levels which are inappropriate because Ofcom erred in adopting the pure LRIC cost standard, rather than the LRIC+ cost standard, as the basis for the charge controls (for the reasons set out in…EE's Notice of Appeal (Ground 1) and of Vodafone's Notice of Appeal."
In short, the referred question which the Competition Commission had to determine on the merits and on the basis of the appellants' grounds of appeal was, whether Ofcom was wrong to impose the pure LRIC and not the LRIC plus cost standard.
The Statutory Scheme
a) promoting efficiency;
b) promoting sustainable competition; and
c) conferring the greatest possible benefits on the end-users of public electronic communications services (s.88(1)(b) of the 2003 Act).
It is on this section that EE places particular reliance. Absent what the Commission described as important evidence on a key issue, EE contends that its endorsement of Ofcom's choice of pure LRIC ran the real risk of imposing a price control standard which failed to achieve the statutory objective of conferring the "greatest possible benefits" on end-users.
Was the Commission Bound to Choose between LRIC and LRIC plus?
"Overall assessment on customer responses
2.700 We accept that care must be taken when assessing survey results. We do not accept that a well-designed survey provides no relevant information. Since the question of consumer responses to price increases is a key issue in this determination, we would normally expect a robust survey to be important evidence that a regulator would seek to rely on. In this case, there does not appear to be any reliable survey evidence that directly addresses the magnitude of customer loss that would flow from the type of price changes we expect to observe. Vodafone and EE's surveys tell us something about the relative effects of different types of price changes, and about the relative impact on low-income customers compared with other customers, although we have been careful in how much weight to place on them.
2.701 The evidence that Ofcom has relied on, primarily about customers' attitudes to mobile phones, is of limited use. Consumers as a whole may have inelastic demand, but that does not mean that there will not be a significant reduction in number of users, especially if price increases are directed towards those with a lower willingness to pay or those who are more price sensitive." (my emphasis)
"1.28 Vodafone cited TalkTalk Telecom Group plc v Ofcom…. as authority for the proposition that the Tribunal (and, hence, the CC) should proceed on the basis that an appeal must succeed if it showed that Ofcom reached the wrong decision or that, in reaching its decision, it applied a methodology which was so unsound as to create a real risk that the decision was wrong. We agree that the proposition largely accords with the matters considered in the Tribunal's judgment in the Wholesale Broadband Access non-price-control judgment. We note, however, that the 'methodology' to which Vodafone refers is in fact the point of process taken in appeal by TalkTalk, rather than the analytical methodology which is subject to scrutiny in the context of these MCT Appeals."
"1.33 We have carried out our examination, in respect of Reference Questions 1 to 6, with the purpose of determining whether Ofcom erred for any of the specific reasons put forward by the parties. In determining whether it did so err, we have not held Ofcom to be wrong simply because we considered there to be some mistake in its reasoning on a particular point—the error in reasoning must have been of sufficient importance to vitiate Ofcom's decision on the point in whole or in part. This is the standard set out in paragraph 1.32 of the MCT Determination and we believe it to be the appropriate approach to the matters at issue in these MCT Appeals."
"2.59 The CC agrees that it must determine whether Ofcom made the 'right' choice and that the appeal should succeed if the appellant can demonstrate that Ofcom applied a methodology which was so unsound as to create a real risk that the decision was wrong (as is the case in our answer to Reference Question 6). In determining whether Ofcom's judgement was wrong in relation to the choice of cost standard the CC takes into account all the factors that Ofcom had to weigh. We do not think that it automatically follows that mistakes in findings of fact that are designed to inform this judgement can render the judgement 'wrong' in the round. The question is whether any mistake is of sufficient importance to vitiate Ofcom's decision as to the appropriate cost standard."
"Where a decision can be challenged by way of a merits appeal, it is incumbent upon an appellant to show – if necessary by way of new evidence – that the original decision was wrong "on the merits". It is not enough to suggest that, were more known, the Tribunal's decision might be different." ([134]of TalkTalk, cited [220])
"Establishing that Ofcom erred might not of itself establish what Ofcom should have done." [3.27]
In such cases the Commission's Guidance provides for separate views to be invited on key issues at a remedies conference [3.28-3.34]. In the instant case the Commission saw no necessity for such a process in relation to EE's and Vodafone's appeals against the choice of pure LRIC.
"It may be that there are cases where Ofcom's approach in reaching its decision was so defective as to preclude the tribunal from reaching an "on the merits" conclusion" (TalkTalk [131] cited by the Tribunal at [219]).
"(It)… means a matter relating to the imposition of any form of price control by an SMP condition the setting of which is authorised by ---
(a) section 87(9)."
These words are sufficiently wide to embrace a determination that Ofcom's decision cannot be maintained. It does not in every case require the Commission to reach an alternative solution.
The Need for Caution
"…an appeal body and no more, a body which can look into whether the regulator has got something materially wrong. That may be very difficult if all that is impugned is an overall value judgment based upon competing commercial considerations in the context of a public policy decision." (T-Mobile (UK) Limited v Office of Communications [2008] EWCA Civ 1371 [31] per Jacob LJ)
The Commission's Determination
"2.731 The appellants argued that Ofcom had underestimated the effects on mobile ownership and subscriptions. Part of that claim is based on their view that Ofcom's reasoning on the pattern of price changes is incorrect. As we discussed above, we find force in that view. However, that also means that some of the arguments made a start from Ofcom's conclusions on price changes rather than the position we have taken. Therefore we apply the parties' logic and evidence as best we can."
This was not an admission that the Commission was relying on evidence which it regarded as inadequate and merely making the best of it. It was doing no more than recognising that some of the arguments were comments on the scale, target and form of price changes predicted by Ofcom. The Commission went on to make its own predictions as to the scale, target and form of such changes.
"2.819 We have also considered evidence on the responsiveness of consumers to price increases. We would normally expect this question to be addressed using empirical evidence, but Ofcom relied on little relevant evidence in its decision and we found that the evidence of the appellants did not allow us to a make a reliable assessment on the scale of reactions to price increases. This is further complicated by the fact that most evidence refers to the number of subscriptions rather than the number of subscribers.719 We did not think that any of the evidence demonstrated that moving from LRIC+ to LRIC would lead to significant reductions in subscriber numbers, relative to the level of subscribers in the UK today."
This was no more than a repeat of its view as to the inadequacies of the survey evidence.
"Overall, in light of the available evidence we find certain aspects of the reasoning of EE, Vodafone and Telefónica convincing and prefer it to Ofcom's, particularly regarding the form of price changes that are likely to follow a reduction in MTRs. We believe that Ofcom's reasoning has led it to underestimate the negative effect on mobile ownership of adopting LRIC in preference to LRIC+. We also consider that there are no good grounds to expect LRIC to cause an increase in mobile usage (an increase or decrease are both possible); and Ofcom may have overstated the increase in fixed usage. However, the appellants have not provided convincing evidence that the scale of decline in the number of users would be significant; and the appellants have not demonstrated that this constitutes a significant negative effect on allocative efficiency. Most of the evidence available relates to the number of subscriptions, and we treat it with caution for three reasons:
(1) most of the available evidence is not robust, is not aimed at the difference between LRIC and LRIC+, or both; (2) it is not clear how a decline in subscriptions translates into a loss of users; and (3) as we set out above, the loss of a subscription that was being subsidized (i.e. its owner valued being on the network less than the cost of being on the network) is not necessarily allocatively inefficient. To the extent that there is some loss of 'efficient' users, that has to be set against all the other effects of higher MTRs (such as higher FTM prices). Therefore we agree with Ofcom that allocative efficiency grounds alone do not provide a clear answer as to whether a LRIC or LRIC+ cost standard should be preferred. For these reasons, bearing in mind the statutory framework within which Ofcom was required to make its decision and the burden being on the appellants to prove that Ofcom erred in its conclusion that LRIC was, in particular, appropriate for the purposes set out in section 88(1)(b) of the Act, and notwithstanding those matters on which our conclusions differ from the conclusions reached by Ofcom under this part 2(a), we do not believe that Ofcom was mistaken, in respect of the appropriateness or otherwise of its choice for promoting efficiency,724 in choosing a LRIC cost standard." [2.823]
"(b) We summarize our views of the challenges to Ofcom's allocative efficiency assessment in paragraph 2.823. Though we do not agree with all aspects of Ofcom's reasoning on allocative efficiency, we agree with Ofcom that allocative efficiency grounds alone do not provide a clear answer as to whether a LRIC or LRIC+ cost standard should be preferred. For these reasons, and notwithstanding those matters on which our conclusions differ from the conclusions reached by Ofcom, we do not believe that Ofcom was mistaken, in respect of the appropriateness or otherwise of its choice for promoting efficiency,852 in choosing a LRIC cost standard. In addition we agreed with Ofcom's conclusion that the adoption of LRIC is likely to have little effect on dynamic efficiency.853" [2.929(b)]
"2.931 There are issues where we find some force in the appellants' arguments. However, in order to find that Ofcom erred in adopting LRIC rather than LRIC+ as a cost standard, we would need to find errors that would materially affect Ofcom's judgement. We do not hold Ofcom to be wrong simply because we consider there to be some error in its reasoning on a particular point—the error in reasoning must have been of sufficient importance to vitiate Ofcom's decision on the point in whole or in part.854 Having regard to our conclusions on the four limbs of assessment, set out in paragraph 2.929, and to the additional support that the Recommendation provides for Ofcom's conclusion we do not believe that it has been demonstrated that Ofcom was wrong in deciding that the LRIC cost standard was appropriate by reference to the statutory duties and considerations in sections 3, 4 and 88 of the Act. Nor do we believe that the appellants have demonstrated that these statutory duties and considerations would have been better served by the setting of the price control by reference to a LRIC+ methodology."
Ground 2: Procedural unfairness
Ground 3: Inconsistency
Lord Justice Patten:
Lord Justice Longmore: