![]() |
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | |
High Court of Ireland Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> High Court of Ireland Decisions >> Duff v. Minister for Agriculture and Food [1999] IEHC 140 (25th March, 1999) URL: http://www.bailii.org/ie/cases/IEHC/1999/140.html Cite as: [1999] IEHC 140 |
[New search] [Printable RTF version] [Help]
1. These
proceedings, which were initiated in this Court by a Plenary Summons issued on
21st February, 1990, have been to the Supreme Court on an appeal from a
judgment of this Court (Murphy J.) of 10th July, 1992. On 14th January, 1993
the Supreme Court referred certain questions to the European Court of Justice
pursuant to Article 177 of the Treaty of Rome, 1957. The judgment of the Court
of Justice was delivered on 15th February, 1996 answering the questions put to
it by the Supreme Court. The judgment of the Supreme Court on the appeal was
delivered on 4th March, 1997. By its Order of 7th March, 1997 the Supreme
Court ordered that:-
2. The
judgment of the High Court and the judgment delivered in the Supreme Court are
reported as
Duff
-v- Minister for Agriculture
(No. 2) [1997] 2 I.R. 22. The judgment of the Court of Justice, with the
opinion of the Advocate General of 8th June, 1995, is reported at [1996] E.C.R.
1-569.
3. The
aspect of the matter currently before this Court is the assessment of damages
in accordance with the Order of the Supreme Court.
4. At
all times the core element in the Plaintiffs' claim has been the application to
them of Article 3 of Council Regulation EEC/857/84 dated 31st March, 1984,
which introduced the regime which is commonly referred to as "the milk super
levy" regime and their contention that, as development farmers, they were
entitled to additional "reference quantity" or, in colloquial terms additional
"milk quota", under that Article. Article 3 provided as follows:-
5. In
simple terms, the Plaintiffs' case at all times has been that they came within
the category of dairy farmer referred to in the first indent of Article 3(1)
and, as such, the first named defendant (the Minister) should have made
provision for the allocation to them of additional quota over and above the
allocation made to the generality of dairy farmers, which was based on actual
deliveries in the calendar year 1983 together with an increment which I will
detail later. However, the Minister, wrongfully the Plaintiffs alleged, made
no special provision for dairy farmers in the category referred to in Article
3(1).
6. At
the original hearing in this Court the Plaintiff's claim was dismissed. In
dismissing it, Murphy J. held, in broad terms, that on the proper
interpretation and application of Article 3(1) a Member State had a
discretionary power to decide whether to allocate additional quota to the
category of dairy farmers referred to therein and that the decision of the
Minister in not exercising the discretionary power was based on national policy
and was not susceptible to review by this Court unless the policy infringed
constitutional rights of the citizen or was shown to involve an abuse of a
fiduciary position, which was not the case. An alternative claim by the
Plaintiffs for damages for negligent advice given by the Minister's servants or
agents was also dismissed.
7. Broadly
speaking, the following propositions of Community law emerged from the answers
of the Court of Justice to the questions referred to it by the Supreme Court,
namely:-
8. However,
on the appeal, the Supreme Court, by a majority (O'Flaherty J., Blayney J. and
Barrington J.), found a remedy in national law for the Plaintiffs. In his
judgment (at page 78 in the report), Barrington J. stated that, in answering
the questions referred by the Supreme Court, the Court of Justice had followed
generally the opinion of the Advocate-General. He went on to quote from the
opinion of the Advocate-General, including the following passage at paragraph
60:-
10. The
remedy under national law which the order of the Supreme Court affords the
Plaintiffs is compensation by way of an award of damages for loss suffered as a
result of the mistake of law of the Minister as found by the Supreme Court. In
order to identify the mistake of law it is necessary to consider the majority
judgments of O'Flaherty and Barrington J., with both of whom Blayney J. agreed,
in some depth. The concept of a remedy in the form of an award of damages for
the consequences of a mistake of law is novel and its application rare, if not
unique to this case. Therefore, this case being, as Mr. Clarke for the
Plaintiffs put it, "almost sui generis", the only real source of guidance for
this Court as to the proper approach to the task which has been remitted to it
are the judgments of O'Flaherty J. and Barrington J.
11. Having
referred to the relevant provisions of Council Regulation EEC/857/84, namely,
Article 3 and Article 5, which provided that for the purpose of applying
Articles 3 and 4 additional reference quantities might be granted only within
the guaranteed quantity limit (in colloquial terms the national quota) and that
these additional quantities "shall be drawn from a reserve constituted by the
Member State within the above mentioned guaranteed quantity" (in other words
from a national reserve within the national quota), O'Flaherty J. stated that
the mistake of law that the Minister made was that he did not constitute a
national reserve at all. While on 7th July, 1984 the Minister had given notice
that he intended to provide for the three special categories set out in Article
3 out of milk available within co-operatives and dairies as a result of
producers ceasing or substantially reducing their deliveries (in other words
out of unused quota - what has come to be known as "flexi milk"), he was
subsequently apprised by the European Commission that the three special
categories could only be provided for out of a national reserve, but there was
no national reserve. O'Flaherty J. then stated (at page 73 in the report):-
12. Different
emphases were attached by Counsel for the Plaintiffs and Counsel for the
Defendants respectively to the majority judgments in the Supreme Court. On
behalf of the Plaintiffs, Mr. Clarke emphasised that at page 74 O'Flaherty J.
stated that, as a matter of national law, the Plaintiffs had a legitimate
expectation that the Minister would honour his commitment that, if they
modernised and developed their holdings, he would see them right and there was
a provision at his disposal, the first indent of Article 3(1), with which he
could keep to his commitment. As a matter of national law on the facts proved,
the Minister could hardly have done anything other than exercise his discretion
in favour of the Plaintiffs. However, through his mistake of law, the Minister
put himself in a position where he could not come to exercise a discretion.
The result was that the persons entitled to expect that a discretion might be
exercised in their favour were unable to get the benefit of that to which they
had a legitimate expectation. O'Flaherty J.'s conclusion was that the
Plaintiffs should be "entitled to a remedy at the hands of the Minister for the
wrongs they have suffered".
13. Relating
the judgment of O'Flaherty J. to the task which this Court has to perform under
the Order of the Supreme Court, in summary, he found that the mistake of law
was the failure to establish the national reserve, in consequence of which the
Minister was unable to exercise the discretion available to him under the first
indent of Article 3(1) to allocate additional quota to the category of dairy
farmers mentioned in that indent, which category includes the Plaintiffs.
14. At
the outset of his judgment Barrington J. quoted the following passage from the
judgment of Murphy J. (which appears at page 32 in the report) as summarising
the position of the Plaintiffs:-
15. On
behalf of the Plaintiffs, Mr. Clarke urged that this Court's approach to its
current task should be informed by that passage and, in particular, by the
finding that the substantial financial and personal investments made by the
Plaintiffs could only be justified by achieving or at least substantially
achieving the output of milk projected in their respective plans.
16. Barrington
J. analysed Article 3 in the context of the Council Regulation as a whole and
in particular in the context of recital 3 and Article 5. He identified the
three categories of dairy farmer who might qualify for additional quota under
Article 3, namely:-
17. In
his judgment (at page 83 in the report), he summarised the effect of Article 3,
recital 3 and Article 5 in the following passage:-
18. Barrington
J. then went on to consider the Minister's decision in principle in relation to
the division of Ireland's national quota and how provision was to be made for
the special categories covered by Article 3, including farmers who had
"invested heavily in milk production", which decision was communicated to the
public in a press release issued by the Government Information Services on 31st
May, 1984, which, for the sake of brevity, I will refer to as "the May 1984
notice", and he commented on the division in the following passage (at page 85
in the report):-
19. Later,
in the following passage (at page 87, in the report) Barrington J. commented on
a notice published by the Minister on 7th July, 1984, which I will refer to as
"the July 1984 notice", setting out his decision as to how the three special
categories of farmers covered by Article 3 were to be catered for out of flexi
milk and the rules to be applied in relation thereto:-
20. Barrington
J. went on to record that when the Minister's mistake was brought home to him
on the Commission refusing to approve his proposal for catering for the special
categories out of flexi milk, and pointing out that he had to make provision
for the mandatory special category, i.e., farmers whose herds during the
reference years suffered from disease or natural disaster, he was forced to do
what he should have done in the first place, that is to say, establish a
national reserve. By a notice dated 17th November, 1984, which I will refer to
as "the November 1984 notice", he announced his intention to make provision for
that mandatory category out of the national reserve established for the
purpose.
21. In
setting out his conclusion (at page 89 et. seq., in the report) Barrington J.
underlined the fact that the Minister did decide to provide for the development
farmers, did decide to provide for them out of the national quota and did
attempt to implement that decision. He then went on to summarise how the
Minister had gone wrong in the following passage which has been emphasised by
Miss Finlay on behalf of the Defendants:-
22. Miss
Finlay submitted that in the last sentence in the above quotation, Barrington
J. was referring to the special reference quantities to which the Plaintiffs
were entitled under the Minister's decision. I have no doubt that this is a
correct interpretation. However, it is perhaps worth noting that it is quite
clear from the judgment of Barrington J. that he identified the Minister's
decision as the decision communicated in the May 1984 notice. He characterised
the July 1984 notice as an attempted implementation of that decision.
23. The
fundamental error identified by Barrington J. was that the method by which the
Minister chose to provide for the development farmers was unlawful; in other
words, that he failed to establish a national reserve. In essence, Barrington
J. concluded that the Plaintiffs are entitled to redress for the damage and
loss they have suffered in consequence of that mistake of law, but he
recognised that it might not now be practicable for the Court or for the
Minister to give them "the outlet for the sale of their milk which they were
led by State agencies to believe that they would get". Instead, the Court
should grant them "damages for all damage and loss they have suffered as a
result of the Minister's mistake of law".
24. Mr.
Clarke emphasised the passage in the judgment of Barrington J. at page 90 in
which he quoted from the July 1984 notice and the reference therein to "farmers
who have invested heavily in milk production and who would be severely
penalised if confined to the basic quota". Barrington J. went on to state:-
25. Relating
the judgment of Barrington J. to the Order of the Supreme Court, in summary, he
found that the fundamental mistake of law was the failure to establish the
national reserve, in consequence of which the Minister was unable to implement
his decision (that is to say, the decision communicated in the May 1984 notice)
to allocate additional quota to the development farmers in exercise of his
discretion under the first indent in Article 3(1).
26. In
his judgment, Barrington J. quoted the May 1984 notice in its entirety,
including the following paragraph which dealt with the categories of farmers
covered by Article 3:-
27. When
one excises the mistake of law from that statement what one is left with is a
decision in principle to make provision for the categories of farmers with
special needs referred to in Article 3 without defining the parameters of the
provision. As to the proper approach for this Court to adopt in assessing the
damages to which the Plaintiffs are entitled, I do not discern any divergence
of principle between the views expressed by O'Flaherty J. and Barrington J. in
their respective judgments.
28. It
was agreed by Counsel on both sides that in assessing the damages to which the
Plaintiffs are entitled for the loss and damage they have suffered as a result
of the Minister's mistake of law, the first issue for the Court is as follows:-
29. Being
satisfied that the approach advocated was the correct approach, I acceded to
the requests that the issue be tried as a preliminary issue. This judgment is
directed to the determination of that issue.
30. It
is agreed that, in order to determine what course of action the Minister would
have adopted had he not fallen into the mistake of law found by the Supreme
Court, it is necessary to consider the factual context in which the Minister
found himself in 1984 as a result of the introduction of the super levy regime
and how he reacted in 1984/85. However, Mr. Clarke suggested a caveat - that
it must be borne in mind that the mistake of law permeated the Minister's
actions almost from the outset. He also suggested that, in deciding what
weight is to be given to the opinions of the Minister's officials, it should be
borne in mind that these opinions are necessarily coloured by events which
should not have happened, but did happen, and cannot now be undone.
31. It
is clear from reading the reports of the earlier proceedings that much of the
evidence adduced at the hearing of the preliminary issue had already been
adduced at the original hearing in this Court in 1992 or had been agreed for
the purposes of the agreed statement of facts which was referred to the Court
of Justice. Nonetheless, at the risk of repetition, it is necessary to outline
the course of events in 1984/85 because no doubt the emphasis was different at
the hearing of the preliminary issue.
32. It
is generally agreed that Ireland was accorded favourable treatment in the super
levy regime. Ireland's guaranteed quantity, i.e. national quota, was to be
based on actual deliveries in the calendar year in 1983. In addition, Ireland
was allocated 245,000 tonnes (equivalent to approximately 52 million gallons)
out of the community reserve. As a result, Ireland's national quota rounded to
millions of gallons, was 1,193 million gallons, which represented 104.6% of
deliveries in the calendar year 1983. Moreover, at the meeting of the Council
of Ministers held in Brussels at the end of March 1984 it was decided that in
the future, when distributing quantities added to the community reserve,
priority would be given to Ireland.
33. Having
achieved a good deal for the Irish milk industry, the Minister was then faced
with the task of distributing the national quota. His approach was to canvass
the views of the industry through consultation with the organisations
representing the co-operatives and the dairies, the purchasers of the milk, and
the farming organisations, which represented the farmers who produced the milk.
At an early stage, with the consensus of the industry representatives, it was
decided to adopt the formula (b) method referred to in Article 3 of allocating
the national quota, so that the quota was to be allocated to the purchasers,
who, in turn, would distribute it amongst their producers, thus fixing
liability for the super-levy at co-operative or dairy level and leaving room
for compensation as between producers affiliated to a particular co-operative
or dairy. A decision then had to be made as to what, if any, part of the
national quota would be put into a national reserve and the basis on which the
quota being allocated would be divided.
34. What
emerges from the evidence is that, prior to the May 1984 notice, one of the
primary objectives of the Minister and of the industry was that the method of
division should ensure that the quota available at national level was filled,
so as to maximise Ireland's prospects of getting priority on distributions of
community reserve in the future, as promised by the Council of Ministers.
There was no enthusiasm in the industry for withholding part of the national
quota to create a national reserve. The preponderance of opinion in the
industry was that the entire of the national quota should be allocated, with a
built in bias in favour of small producers on the division amongst the
producers. The most the co-operatives and dairies would countenance being
withheld from the national quota to create the national reserve was 0.23%. The
farming organisations were opposed to any part of the national quota being
withheld to create a national reserve and suggested that the national reserve
be created by the implementation of a discontinuation premium system.
35. These
views must be seen against the background of the then current belief that the
special provision permitted for the special categories covered by Article 3
could be catered for by permanent allocation of the quota freed within a
co-operative or dairy as a result of non delivery or substantially reduced
delivery. It would appear, however, that no real consideration was given to
the extent to which the special needs of the special categories could be met
under such arrangement. However, as appears from a discussion paper which was
circulated at a meeting of officials from the Minister's department and
representatives of the milk industry held on 23rd May, 1984, it was envisaged
that the special provision would be applied on the basis of an order of
priority amongst the special categories inter se. The farmers within Article
3(3) would have priority, those affected by animal disease (to whom I will
refer as the "animal disease category") having priority over the remainder (to
whom I will refer as the "other disaster category"). Next in line of priority
would be the farmers who came within Article 3(2) (to whom I will refer as the
"new entrant category"). At the bottom of the priority list were farmers who
came within Article 3(1) who had invested heavily in milk production and would
be unfairly penalised if confined to basic quota (to whom I will refer as the
"investment category"). It was envisaged that the investment category would
include the farmers involved in the rescue package. It was also envisaged that
the provision for the investment category would be subject to a limit related
to the annual target in the relevant milk improvement plan. It does not
appear, however, that there was any in-depth analysis at that stage of the
needs of the various categories inter se and, in particular, of the needs of
the new entrant category vis-à-vis the investment category.
36. At
that stage the consultation process was not specifically targeted at
identifying and meeting the needs of the special categories, although Macra na
Feirme, which represents young farmers, sought, unsuccessfully at that stage,
to be involved in the consultation process and representations were made on
behalf of the investment category by the Deputy Chief Executive of Agricultural
Credit Corporation Limited (A.C.C.).
37. While
there seems to have been a general awareness that because of the parlous state
of the national finances, monies would not be forthcoming from the exchequer to
fund a cessation scheme, it would not appear that this method of creating a
national reserve was considered to any degree.
38. It
is fair to say that the decision reflected in the May 1984 notice, which was
the decision which the Supreme Court found to be erroneous in law, in general
terms was in accordance with the views of the milk industry. The entire of the
national quota was to be allocated, the division at producer level reflecting a
bias in favour of small producers. No national reserve was to be created and
the special categories were to be catered for out of flexi milk.
39. The
next major step was the publication of the July 1984 notice, which Barrington
J. categorised as the Minister's attempt to implement the erroneous decision he
had made in the previous May to provide for the special categories out of flexi
milk. What emerges from the evidence in relation to the interim period between
the two notices is that the detail of the provision for the special categories
was worked out against an expectation that the quantity of flexi milk which
would be available would be 2% of national production. It is also clear that
what had been mooted in the discussions with the industry representatives
before the May 1984 notice in relation to the detail, in particular, the
classes within the special categories to be provided for and the order of
priority to be applied in making provision for them was not regarded as having
been "writ in stone". The arrangements set out in the July 1984 notice, which
were stated to be subject to the approval of the Commission, made provision for
the animal disease category, but not the other disaster category, it clearly
not being recognised that the provision for this latter category was mandatory,
not discretionary. It also made provision for the new entrant category and the
investment category. Flexi milk was to be distributed to the three categories
on the basis of not less than 50% for the animal disease category, and not more
than 25% each for the new entrant category and the investment category. In
other words, the investment category was accorded equal priority with the new
entrant category. If there was sufficient availability of flexi milk and
sufficient demand from the three categories, co-operatives and dairies were to
be obliged to allocate up to 2% of their quotas to the three categories. Any
other flexi milk available might be allocated to producers, especially young
farmers, who were increasing their deliveries. The terms of the July 1984
notice suggest to me that even by July 1984 no reliable data was available to
the Minister of the amount of quota which would have been needed to make
provision for the special categories or the extent to which 2% of national
quota would have met the provision which the Minister was obliged and entitled
to make under Article 3 for the special categories. The generality of the
evidence bears this out.
40. The
Commission did not approve of the arrangements set out in the July 1984 notice
and by September 1984 the Minister had been apprised that the provisions of
Article 3(3) were obligatory on member states, that such provision could only
be made out of a national reserve and that permanent reallocations of quota, as
had been proposed in the July 1984 notice, could not be made out of flexi milk.
Faced with this dilemma, the Minister had no alternative but to establish a
national reserve to cater for the animal disease category and the other
disaster category. Indeed, after the publication of the July 1984 notice and
before the bad news came from Brussels, there was a certain amount of clamour
from the industry for the introduction of a cessation scheme under which the
exchequer would fund the "buying in" of quota from which a national reserve
would be established. By the time the bad news came from Brussels the division
of the entire national quota which had been announced in the May 1984 notice
had been "fine tuned" and it was decided that the division at producer level
would be on the basis that the reference quantity (quota):-
41. While
the notice of this decision sent to the co-operatives and dairies on 31st July,
1984 made it clear that the division was on a "tentative basis" until the
arrangements in relation to the special categories had been cleared by the
Commission, the division on this basis was never subsequently altered. In my
view, the only reasonable inference to be drawn from the evidence is that by
September 1984 it would not have been politic or practical for the Minister to
vary that decision in such a way as to "claw back" from the generality of
producers quota which they had been told four months earlier had been allocated
to them.
42. In
October 1984 the Minister sought the sanction of the Minister of Finance to
introduce a milk cessation scheme to buy in 7 million gallons of quota at a
total cost of £5 million to create a national reserve to provide for the
animal disease category and the other disaster category. The sanction was
ultimately granted but subject to certain conditions, including a condition
that the cost would be met by "suitable savings" on the allocations for the
Department of Agriculture which had already been decided for the years 1985 to
1987.
43. The
introduction of the milk cessation scheme was announced in the November 1984
notice. The provision to be made for the animal disease category and the other
disaster category out of the 7 million gallons of quota expected to become
available under the cessation scheme was also announced in that notice. As
regards the other special categories, namely, the new entrant category and the
investment category, it was announced that the Commission had ruled that
permanent reallocation could not be made on the basis of reduced delivery by
producers. Co-operatives and dairies were asked to cater for these categories
"on the basis of temporary allocations each year out of the milk that comes
available within their areas as a result of reduction in deliveries by
producers below the level of their individual quotas". In relation to the
investment category, it was announced that, in accordance with the guidelines
already published, the temporary reallocation should "when added to his basic
quota be subject to a maximum of the annual target in his improvement plan".
The November 1984 notice went on to state as follows:-
44. In
early 1985 the Minister came under renewed pressure to make permanent provision
for the new entrant category. Ultimately on 1st July, 1985 the Minister
announced that permanent allocation for the new entrant category would be made
from a national reserve to be established by "staggered" deductions from the
quota which larger producers had enjoyed in the 1984/85 quota year, the
deductions ranging in size from 0.25% from quotas between 20,000 and 30,000
gallons and 1.25% in the case of quotas which exceeded 80,000 gallons. From
the reserve thus created permanent additional quotas were to be allocated to
new entrants who commenced milk deliveries between 1st January, 1983 and 21st
May, 1984. However, there was to be a cap on the additional quota, in that
each beneficiary would benefit only up to the average delivery level of his
co-operative or dairy. The terms of the scheme were set out in a notice
published by the Minister on 9th August, 1985, which I will refer to as "the
August 1985 notice".
45. Accordingly,
by mid-1985 the Minister had made permanent provision under two of the
sub-articles of Article 3: under Sub-article (2) for the new entrant category,
in respect of which he had a discretion; and under Sub-article (3) for the
mandatory animal disease category and other disaster category. He never made
permanent provision under Sub-article (1) for the investment category.
46. The
out-turn of the schemes implemented by the Minister under Sub-articles (2) and
(3) of Article 3 is interesting, although this data became available much
later.
47. Under
the cessation scheme announced in the November 1984 notice 7.2 million gallons
was surrendered and reallocated. Producers in the animal disease category got
100% of the difference between the higher of their 1981 or 1982 deliveries and
their 1983 deliveries and producers in the other disaster category got 52% of
the same difference.
48. The
"staggered" deductions made under the August 1985 notice released 5.7 million
gallons which were reallocated on the basis that the producers in the new
entrant category provided for under that scheme got 56.5% of the difference
between 1984/85 deliveries and 1983 deliveries subject to the cap provided for
in the scheme.
49. In
my view there are two distinct elements in the approach the Minister would, as
a matter of probability, have adopted in allocating additional quota to the
investments category had he not fallen into the error of law identified by the
Supreme Court.
50. First,
he would have had to identify the "difference" he was permitted by Article 3(1)
to take account of in granting a special reference quantity. Secondly, he
would have had to decide to what extent he was going to fill that difference or
shortfall; whether he was going to fully fill it by granting additional quota
equivalent to 100% of the difference or whether he was only going to partially
fill it. The first element, in my view, is primarily a matter of
interpretation of Article 3 to ascertain what the Minister was empowered to do.
The second element raises broader issues - issues of what was feasible,
practical and politic in the circumstances prevailing in 1984. It involves
consideration of the following questions:-
51. I
think it is important to bear in mind that the Minister was under a certain
time constraint when making the decisions he had to make in relation to Article
3. The first quota year, 1984/85 commenced in April 1984. Milk production is
seasonal and about 80% of milk is produced in the months from April to October.
Commission Regulation EEC 1371/84, setting out the detailed rules in relation
to the super-levy system, was not published until 16th May, 1984.
52. The
farm modernisation schemes, which gave effect in this jurisdiction to Council
Directive 72/159/EEC are described in outline in the judgment of Murphy J. (at
pages 28 and 29 in the report). From each dairy farmer's plan, which was drawn
up in conjunction with his ACOT adviser, it is possible to ascertain his
targeted milk production over the duration of the plan, usually five or six
years. Targeted milk production in any year represented the product of his
projected cow numbers and projected milk yield per cow in that year. While the
projected yield may not have been expressly stated on the face of each plan, it
can be ascertained by deconstructing the figures for gross margin shown in the
plan, which were arrived at by using guidelines issued to ACOT advisers - a
type of "ready reckoner" into which the projected yield was factored.
53. The
Defendants case is that the Minister's decision to make provision under Article
3(1) would have been based on the difference between:-
54. The
Plaintiffs' opening position varied somewhat from their closing position on the
"difference" element and this variation is largely attributable to terminology
problems. In any event, the Plaintiffs' opening position was that the Minister
would have based the allocation on the difference between:-
55. The
Plaintiffs' closing position was that, subject to two refinements, the Minister
would have based his allocation on the difference between:-
56. The
first of the two refinements to that general approach suggested by the
Plaintiffs was that a participant in the farm modernisation scheme who was
certified by ACOT as not being in compliance with his development plan in
1983/1984 would only be allocated quota based on his deliveries in 1983. I
assume that this refinement was suggested because of a perceived inequity to
which I will refer later. Secondly, in the case of a participant whose actual
cow numbers in the end year of the plan exceeded the projected cow numbers for
that year, it was suggested that his targeted milk production should be based
on his actual production in the end year adjusted in proportion to the
projected number of cows in accordance with the following formula:-
58. The
first major area of disagreement between the Defendants and the Plaintiffs in
relation to the "difference" element relates to the target figure for the end
of plan and, broadly speaking, the divergence is that the Plaintiffs submit
that the target figure should be based on actual yield, rather than planned
yield, in the end year of the plan. They justify this approach on the basis
that the projected yield figures included in the plans were conservative and
were mainly directed towards the classification of participants into one or
other of the classes of participants provided for in the farm modernisation
scheme. In short, they submit that the projected yield figures were not true
projections and were generally below what was generally regarded in the
industry as achievable yield and what participants in the farm modernisation
scheme were expected to achieve on the basis of their investment. In my view,
it is improbable that the Minister would have succumbed in 1984 to an argument
that the target figure should have an "actual" component. I think it highly
improbable that he would have withheld any part of the national quota in any
year to await completion of development plans. Moreover, I have no doubt that
he would have baulked at the practical and administrative difficulties which
would have been involved in including an "actual" component in the target
figure. What I believe would have been foremost in the Minister's mind was the
provision he was entitled to make for the investment category under the first
indent of Article 3(1). In
Cornée
-v- Co-operative Agricole Laitière de Loudeac (Cases 196-198/88)
,
[1989] E.C.R. 2309, the Court of Justice in its judgment, having stated that it
is clear that Article 3(1) grants Member States a discretionary power to decide
whether special reference quantities should be allocated to the producers
mentioned in that provision and, if so, to determine their size, in paragraph
14, which is quoted in the judgment of Murphy J. (at page 35 in the report),
stated as follows:-
59. It
must be assumed that had the Minister exercised his discretion under Article
3(1) in 1984 he would have realised that under Community law what he had to
take into account was the production objective provided for in development
plans. Therefore, I find that, as a matter of probability, that the target
figure would have been based on the projected cow numbers and projected yield
in the end year of plan and not on actual or notional herd size or yield.
60. The
parties also disagree fundamentally as to the baseline of the "difference"
element and, broadly speaking, the Defendants' contention is that it should be
planned deliveries for 1983, assuming planned deliveries were greater than
actual deliveries, whereas the Plaintiffs submit that it should be the actual
deliveries in 1983 on which the quota, if any, which a development farmer
acquired was based. The Defendants' position is that when the super-levy
scheme was introduced on 1st April, 1984 what it did was to potentially
interfere with increases in production under development plans which were
on-going at that date and accordingly, what the Minister would have done in
applying Article 3(1) was to have regard to the planned increase in production
from 1st April, 1984 until the end of plan as shown in the development plan
because that was what potentially was interfered with by the super-levy system.
While I can appreciate the force of that argument, it seems to me that it does
not take account of the fact that return, in the form of increased production,
on an investment under a development plan does not occur at uniform rate and,
as the evidence indicates, investment tends to be, as it were, "front-loaded",
with the return coming later.
61. It
was also suggested by the Defendants that there would be inequities inherent in
using actual, as opposed to planned, production for 1983 as the baseline. One
such inequity was exemplified by comparing two farmers, farmer A and farmer B,
involved in six year plans which commenced on 1st January, 1981 and were due to
terminate on 31st December, 1986 and each of whose targeted production for end
of plan was 60,000 gallons and each of whose planned production for 1983 was
30,000. If actual production for 1983 is the baseline, and farmer A actually
achieved 30,000 gallons in that year and farmer B actually achieved only 10,000
gallons in that year, the differential in the case of farmer A would be 20,000
gallons, whereas in the case of farmer B it would 50,000 gallons. This is
perceived as an inequity and it may well be an inequity, if farmer B's failure
to achieve his 1983 target was due to some fault on his part. However, I think
it is improbable that the Minister or his advisers would have looked at the
matter in this way in deciding on the baseline. The focus at this juncture in
these proceedings is on compensating the Plaintiffs for the failure to allocate
additional quota to them in consequence of the mistake of law made in 1984.
The focus in 1984 would have been to "top up" a development farmer's basic
quota. I do not think that an assumption would have been made in 1984 that
failure to have achieved a target in 1983 was indicative of some default on the
part of the farmer. It may well be that in the next round of these
proceedings, when compensation is being assessed, an issue will arise as to
whether somebody in farmer B's situation would have ever reached end target.
However, that is a separate issue for another day.
62. Such
contemporaneous documentary evidence as exists suggests to me that had he
exercised his discretion in favour of the investment category in 1983, the
Minister would have used quota actually allocated, which was based on actual
production in 1983, as the baseline for the differential. Both the July 1984
notice and the November 1984 notice envisage an addition to "basic quota" for
the investment category subject to a maximum based on targeted production in
the development plan. I think it is implicit in both notices that the baseline
would be the basic quota, not an artificial baseline which did not reflect the
then reality for dairy farmers in the investment category.
63. The
Plaintiffs' case is that the Minister could have and would have given
additional quota to fill the difference fully, that is to say, that the
additional quota would have been equivalent to 100% of the difference. The
basis of this proposition was that there was no legal impediment to creating a
national reserve which was large enough to make full provision for all of the
special categories mentioned in Article 3. Furthermore, it was argued that
there was no practical impediment to creating a national reserve which would
have achieved that purpose. In particular, it was submitted that the Court
should reject the Defendants' argument that it would have been politically
impossible for the Minister to have failed to make a significant allocation
above the 1983 production level to the generality of farmers. The expectations
of the farming organisations that the allocation would allow for an "across the
board" increase over 1983 production levels was fuelled, it was suggested, to
some extent by pronouncements made by the Minister on the basis of his
erroneous view of the law. The attitude of the farming organisations might
have been different, it was suggested, if both the Minister and the
representatives of the farming organisations were not labouring under a
misapprehension as to the true legal position. It was also submitted that it
was not the case that an allocation based on an "across the board" increase on
1983 production levels was necessary to achieve policy objectives,
particularly, the policy of filling the national quota. An alternative
proposition put forward by the Plaintiffs, albeit on the basis that it was
unduly restrictive, was that the entirety of the additional allocation to
Ireland from the Community reserve, which amounted to approximately 52 million
gallons, could have been used to establish the national reserve to cater for
the special categories mentioned in Article 3. It was also submitted by the
Plaintiffs that it was open to the Court to find that, had a proper case been
made to the Department of Finance at the outset, a cessation scheme funded from
exchequer might have been sanctioned, because the debate between the Minister
for Agriculture and the Minister for Finance when sanction was sought in
October 1984 was not so much fiscal as ideological, whether a cessation scheme
was a proper method of intervention.
64. The
Defendants' case is that the Minister would have allocated additional quota
sufficient only to fill 17% of the differential and in reaching this conclusion
the Defendants addressed the questions which I have outlined earlier as follows:-
66. Some
small deduction, in the order of 0.33 million gallons, might be made from the
foregoing total to allow for overlap between categories, it is conceded.
67. On
the basis of their answers to the questions, which I have outlined, the
Defendants' assessment of the extent to which the Minister would have met the
differential is calculated at 17% as follows:-
68. There
are a number of points to be made about the Defendants' quantification of the
demand for additional quota for the investment category. First, the
Plaintiffs' estimation of the total requirement, based on the evidence of Dr.
Nicholas Bielenberg, who was constrained to rely on such data as emerged from
the Defendants' discovery, was in the region of 41 million gallons. The
difference between the Defendants' estimation of the total requirement and the
Plaintiffs' is largely attributable to the fact that Dr. Bielenberg believes,
on the basis of his own experience, that there was a substantial overlap
between all of the special categories. The reality, however, is that the
Plaintiffs are not in a position to challenge most of the data relied on by the
Defendants. By way of general observation, I find the data on which the
Defendants' estimates are based to be reliable and the methodology used by the
Defendants in estimation to be reasonable.
69. Secondly,
on the basis that what the Minister would have done, had he not fallen into
error and had he exercised his discretion in favour of the investment category,
is that he would have taken into account the difference between targeted milk
production for the end year of the plan and actual production for 1983, as I
have held it is probable he would have, the Defendants' foregoing estimates
require adjustment. For instance, the Defendants' estimation of the
requirement of dairy farmers who were planned under the Farm Modernisation
Scheme between January 1981 and the end of March 1984 at 27.8 million gallons
assumes that actual production in 1983 represented only 85% of planned
production, so that in using actual production as the baseline the total
requirement for this category would have been 8.1 million gallons higher.
Similarly, the Defendants' estimation of the requirement of dairy farmer
participants in the rescue package at 27.5 million gallons embodies an
adjustment downwards of approximately 3.5 million gallons to take account of
the divergence between actual achievement and target on the part of such
participants, so that in using actual production as the baseline the total
requirement for this category would have been 3.5 million gallons higher.
Accordingly, if the Defendants had used the actual production in 1983 as the
baseline, it is to be assumed that they would have quantified the demand for
additional quota from the investment category at an excess of 78 million
gallons.
70. It
is not an easy task to determine to what extent the Minister would have filled
the differential in 1984, had he addressed the issue properly. Factors other
than strict legal principles would have come into play: matters of national
policy, milk industry politics, and so forth. On the basis of the evidence I
do not think it probable that the Minister could have seen his way to meet the
differential fully. On the other hand, I do not think that he would have
introduced a scheme which would have met only 17% of the differential.
71. Such
a scheme would have highlighted a glaring disparity between the treatment of
the investment category and the treatment of the other special categories. The
evidence does not suggest to me that the Minister would have accorded the
lowest priority to the investment category. While there would clearly have
been justification for treating the animal disease category more favourably
and, indeed, giving them a 100% allocation as in fact happened in late 1984,
because of their mandatory status under Article 3 and also because of the
evident sympathy for their plight in the industry generally, I cannot see how
the Minister could have justified treating the investment category so
disproportionately less favourable than the new entrant category. The evidence
from 1984 and, in particular, the July 1984 notice clearly indicates that the
Minister's thinking at the time was that the investment category and the new
entrant category were entitled to equal priority.
72. If
one considers the position of the second named Plaintiff, Liam Finlay, who
testified at the hearing of the preliminary issue, the inescapable conclusion
is that provision which would have met only 17% of the differential would have
appeared to be derisory in 1984. In using the figures from Mr. Finlay's plan
for the period from 1982 to 1986, as I propose, I must emphasise that I am
using them on a crude basis for illustrative purposes only. I am conscious
that Mr. Finlay testified that he was not aware until 1992 that a projected
yield of 700 gallons, per cow had been provided for in his plan and that, while
his actual deliveries in 1983 were in the region of 16,500 to 17,000 gallons,
he was allocated a quota of 22,000 gallons. Leaving aside those matters, which
are for another day, under Mr. Finlay's plan projected cow numbers for the end
of plan were 50 and the projected yield was 700 gallons, so that his targeted
milk production for the end of plan was 35,000 gallons. If one takes the
baseline, his quota based on his actual production for 1983, at 17,000 gallons
for simplicity (roughly 16,500 gallons plus 3.55%), on the Defendants' case the
additional quota which would have been allocated to him, but for the Minister's
mistake of law, would have been 17% of 18,000 gallons or 3,060 gallons. The
effect of this provision would have been that he would have been able to
produce milk without penalty up to a threshold of 20,060 gallons or 57% of the
outcome which had been projected for him on the basis of the investment to be
undertaken under his plan.
73. Had
the Minister been devising a scheme to cover all the special categories out of
a national reserve shortly after the introduction of the super levy system in
1984, in my view, it is probable that he would have devised a scheme which
would have provided that the investment category would be allocated additional
quota equivalent to 50% of the differential. I must acknowledge that the only
reasonable inference to be drawn from the evidence is that the Minister would
have had to draw on a national reserve to an extent probably in the range of 30
million gallons to 40 million gallons to make such provision, which when
coupled with the total requirements of the other special categories, for whom I
consider it probable the Minister would have made the provision he actually
made in 1984 and 1985, would have necessitated the establishment of a national
reserve with a capacity in the range of 43 million gallons to 53 million
gallons. While the probability is that in making such provision, the Minister
would have absorbed most if not all of Ireland's allocation from the Community
reserve, had the Minister not been in the position in which he found himself in
1984, in short, to adopt the metaphor used by Barrington J., of having to
"unscramble the egg", I think it is probable that he could have justified that
approach to the industry. In providing for the investment category, the
Minister would have been providing for a considerably greater number of
producers than were actually provided for when the other special categories in
1984 and 1985. In all 5,372 producers were provided for under Article 3(2) and
Article 3(3) in 1984 and 1985. On the Defendants' figures, in excess of 13,000
producers would have been catered for had provision been made for the
investment category under Article 3(1). However, I think it would have been
impossible for the Minister to draw on the portion of the national quota based
on actual deliveries in 1983 to augment the national reserve, as this would
have been unacceptable to the generality of dairy farmers.
74. It
is clear from the contemporary documentary evidence available that the
perception of the Minister and his officials of dairy farmers within the
investment category in 1984 was of a group of people who would be severely
penalised if they were confined to basic quota. If one resorts to the figures
in Mr. Finlay's plan once again for illustrative purposes, provision of 50% of
the differential for Mr. Finlay would have resulted in an additional allocation
of 9,000 gallons to him, which on top of his basic quota, would have given him
26,000 gallons or 74% of the planned out-turn of his investment. It is
difficult to see how, had he been approaching the matter on a proper legal
basis, the Minister could have stood over any lesser provision.
75. Finally,
the evidence is not sufficiently cogent to lead to the conclusion that the
Minister would have been justified in being concerned that such provision, more
than any of the measures which were actually adopted in 1984/1985, would have
jeopardised the national policy of filling quota, even though in the early
years of the super-levy regime set off of deficits and surpluses as between
purchasers at national level was not permitted.
76. The
answer to the question posed in the preliminary issue is that, as a matter of
probability, the Plaintiffs and other farmers who had invested heavily in milk
production would have been allocated additional quota in 1984/85 if the
Minister had not committed the error of law found by the Supreme Court in its
judgments herein according to the following formula:-