DECISION
1.
Mr Bretten appeals against an HMRC amendment made to his self assessment
tax return for the year 2002/03. The amendment was made when HMRC closed an
enquiry into his tax return for that year on 31 May 2011. The effect of the
amendment was to increase Mr Bretten’s charge to income tax by denying him the
claimed loss of £475,000.
Facts
The evidence
2.
Apart from the documentary evidence, witness evidence was given by Mr
Bretten.
3.
I find as follows:
The Transactions
4.
On 18 February 2003 Mr Bretten established two UK-resident trusts, which
were referred to in the hearing and to which I will refer to in this decision
notice, as Trust 1 and Trust 2. Mr Bretten established each of them with a
nominal trust fund of £10.
5.
Trust 1: the trustees of Trust 1 were the appellant and the
appellant’s daughter, Mrs S Cox. Mr Bretten was the life tenant of this trust
with the remainder held for the Mr Bretten’s children with charities as the
ultimate default beneficiary.
6.
Trust 2: the trustees of Trust 2 were the appellant and his
daughter’s husband, Mr A Cox. Mrs S Cox was the life tenant of this trust, and
the remainder was held for Mrs Cox’ children with charities as the ultimate
default beneficiary.
7.
Oakcrown Consultants Limited (“OCL”) was a company established in 2002
and owned by the partners of a firm of accountants. It was not connected to Mr
Bretten.
8.
The call option: It was a condition precedent to Mr Bretten’s
subscription for the loan notes mentioned below that OCL first granted a call
option to Trust 1 which would allow Trust 1 to be substituted as debtor (or obligor)
in place of OCL for an amount equal to the redemption price of the loan notes
mentioned below. That option was granted by OCL to Trust 1 on 24 February
2003.
9.
On the same day, OCL issued six loan notes at face value to the Bretten
in return for £500,000. (Four of the loan notes were for £100,000 and two for
£50,000).
10.
The loan notes: the terms of the six loan notes were identical.
They would mature on 30 April 2043 (a term of 40 years). They carried a
maturity premium of 25% and an interest rate of 0.25% per annum payable on 31
December each year.
11.
Significantly for this appeal they carried the right of early
redemption:
(a)
On written notice given before the 10th day after issue they
were redeemable at the noteholder’s option for 100% of the issue price;
(b)
On written notice given after the 9th day of issue but
before the 15th day of issue they could be redeemed at the
noteholder’s option for 99.9% of the issue price (£499,500);
(c)
On written notice given after the 14th day following
issue but before the expiry of the first year after issue, they were redeemable
at the noteholder’s option for 5% of the issue price (in total £25,000).
12.
For the first 90 days after issue the loan notes were secured by a
charge over OCL’s money deposits or other investments. In reality, this
security was only in place until the call option was exercised (when OCL would
cease to be the issuer) and it was always intended that the call option would
be exercised during the first 14 days (as indeed it was).
13.
The loan notes were (save for the first 7 days after issue) freely
transferable. And the issuer had the power to substitute any company listed in
the FTSE 250 or any person connected with the noteholder.
14.
Clause 5 of the loan notes provided for automatic redemption at issue
price of the loan notes if the FTSE 100 index exceeded 4000. Mr Bretten said
he placed no reliance on this clause. He agreed that it was inserted to make
the loan notes more robust from a tax avoidance point of view by inserting a
genuine if remote uncertainty.
15.
Exercise of call option: on 5th March 2003 the
trustess of Trust 1 (Mr Bretten and Mrs Cox) gave notice to OCL that they were
exercising the call option granted to them on 24 February 2003. On that same
date OCL and the trustees of Trust 1 entered into an agreement the effect of
which was to substitute the trustees as the issuer of the loan notes and
discharge OCL from liability on them: and in accordance with this agreement
OCL paid £499,500 to the trustees.
16.
We note for the sake of completeness but it has no bearing on the case
that £499,500 was thought to be the redemption value of the loan notes but the
parties made a slight miscalculation. March 5th was the 9th
and not 10th day after issue of the loan notes so the redemption
price was actually £500,000. Technically OCL still owes Trust 1 £500 but this
had not been demanded or paid.
17.
Gift of loan notes: on the same day, Mr Bretten gifted the loan
notes to Trust 2. The end result was that Trust 1 had £499,500 in cash but
liability on the loan notes: Trust 2 became the noteholder. It did not
exercise its right to redeem the loan notes, and that right has now of course
expired with the passage of time.
18.
As at the date of the hearing, some 10 years later, the position was
unchanged: Trust 1 had retained the £499,500 and liability on the loan notes.
Trust 2 remained possessed of the loan notes.
19.
Valuation of loan notes: no formal valuation of the loan notes
was produced in evidence but the parties were agreed that as at the date of
issue the loan notes’ value was approximately their face or issue value. This
was because for effectively the first 14 days of issue they carried the right
of redemption at issue price (or in the last 5 days, issue price less £500).
20.
There was a dispute about the market value of the RDS at the
moment of issue for the purposes of Schedule 13 (see paragraph 53 below). Mr
Bretten conceded, and I find, that the market value of the RDS at the moment of
issue was less than the face value because a willing purchaser could
redeem them for no more than £500,000 and therefore, were they to purchase
them, would expect to pay less than this in order to make a small profit and
cover their costs.
21.
The parties were also agreed that the value of the loan notes after the
first 14 days of issue was no more than (in total) £25,000. This was because
for the first year (after the initial 15 days) the loan notes could be redeemed
at 5% of face value which was (in total) £25,000. Both parties were also
agreed that thereafter (in so far as relevant to the appeal) the value of the
loan notes on the open market would be even lower: they could not be redeemed
until 2043 and, as they were no longer secured, it was unlikely a third party
would pay very much at all for all such a distant and uncertain return.
Planned transactions and motive
22.
It was not in dispute that these transactions were intended although not
bound to happen.
23.
These transactions were not circular. The end result was that Mr
Bretten had half a million pounds less in capital than he started with:
although this may well have made little practical difference to him as he was
the life tenant of the trust in which that half million pounds (minus what was
seen as a transaction fee of £500) ended up vested. What he had done was
swopped absolute entitlement to £500,000 to entitlement only to the income from
that sum of money.
24.
So far as inheritance tax was concerned, Mr Bretten was satisfied that
these arrangements gave rise to no liability (as he was the life tenant of
trust 1) and HMRC do not suggest otherwise.
25.
His reason for putting half a million of his assets into a trust was not
tax avoidance. Rather it was to avoid potential creditors. Mr Bretten was a
“name” at Lloyds and at the time of these transactions there was a perception
that he (and many other Names) were at risk of large future liabilities. I do
not need to consider whether putting assets into a trust in this manner would
be successful in its creditor-avoidance objective: I find that this was the
ultimate objective, whether or not it succeeded.
26.
The method of transferring the assets to the trust (using loan
notes issued by OCL) I find, as Mr Bretten stated, was planned and intended
to be tax efficient. In particular, it was intended to generate a loss of
£475,000 for Mr Bretten. (The intended loss was £475,000 because it was the
issue price of the loan notes at £500,000 less the £25,000 which the parties
agreed was their market value as at the date of their transfer by Mr Bretten to
Trust 2).
27.
Mr Bretten agreed that if asset protection had been his only concern he
would have transferred the £500,000 direct to Trust 1 or even given it to his
wife, as indeed he transferred a number of assets to his wife at this time.
The loan notes transactions were undertaken solely for tax avoidance reasons.
28.
He also agreed that there were features of the loan notes that were
inserted solely to bolster the tax planning. In particular, it was his
evidence he would have been content had there been one loan note issued for
£500,000 but he went along with the suggestion of Mr Harris (a partner in the
firm of accountants which owned OCL) of having 4 loan notes at £100,000 and 2
at £50,000. Mr Bretten referred to clause 5 as a “built-in anti-Ramsay
device”. The idea was to build in an element of randomness so that the courts
could not say the transactions was pre-ordained. Again, this clause was Mr
Harris’s suggestion, and one in which Mr Bretten says he did not have
confidence, but he thought it did no harm. In the event, of course, Mr Brettten
does not rely on it in any way to support his case.
29.
The loan notes carried interest solely because it was perceived as
important to make them look commercial. A low rate of interest was selected to
avoid a material income tax liability. There was no particular reason why a 40
year term was selected: other than that it was necessary for the term to be
long so that the valuation at date of transfer should be negligible, the term
was irrelevant to Mr Bretten.
OCL’s involvement
30.
It was agreed that OCL was owned and controlled by a third party. It
was Mr Bretten’s evidence that the firm of accountants who owned and controlled
OCL understood the tax planning and indeed agreed to the participation by OCL
on the understanding that they would in effect get a fee of £500 (by the option
being exercised after day 9) to cover their costs plus have the right to
replicate the planning for their clients.
31.
Mr Bretten agreed that OCL did not require a loan of £500,000 and OCL’s
involvement with the loan and loan notes was and was always intended to be
short lived. I find its involvement was solely to facilitate the tax
planning. It had no other purpose.
32.
Mr Bretten agreed he would not have loaned £500,000 to OCL were it not
for the security provided by OCL and its grant of the call option to Trust 1.
In other words, OCL’s involvement was virtually risk free to Mr Bretten. The
cash given to OCL was secured by a charge over the money and could not
therefore be spent or lost by OCL and Mr Bretten could in any event cause Trust
1 to exercise its option to call for the money and substitute itself for OCL as
the debtor under the loan notes.
33.
I find OCL’s grant of the call option and its issue of the loan notes
was done solely to facilitate Mr Bretten’s tax avoidance scheme.
34.
Mr Bretten agreed that he could have done the same planning scheme and
cut out OCL entirely by using a trust. He did not do this because he had
concerns that the grant of the loan notes needed to be issued by a corporate
body and not a trust. He said (and I accept) that he did not choose OCL
because he was concerned about the application of paragraph 9A of Schedule 13
(an anti-avoidance provision discussed below): he did not think paragraph 9A
would apply in any event because in his view the RDS would be issued at full
value.
35.
However, the tenor of his evidence was, and indeed he had already
accepted in a letter to HMRC, that the arrangements that were implemented would
not have been chosen by him as the most convenient way of sheltering his
assets. So I find that the incorporation of OCL into the scheme was solely in
order to facilitate the tax avoidance.
The 14 day redemption rights
36.
As outlined above, for the first 14 days that loan notes existed, Mr
Bretten (or Trust 2 after the notes were donated to it on day 9) had the right
to redeem the loan notes for face value or (day 10 to day 14) for face value
less £500.
37.
HMRC’s case was that this redemption right was inserted solely for tax
avoidance reasons. It was there so that market value of the securities would
be virtually their issue price for the first 14 days of their existence so that
it would not be possible to say that they were granted at an undervalue.
38.
Mr Bretten’s evidence was that there was a dual motive to the 14 day
redemption rights. He accepted that he saw it as necessary to establish that
the loan notes were worth what he paid for them but he said he also saw it as a
cooling off period. His evidence was that he had concerns about (a) whether he
as a tax barrister should enter into a tax avoidance scheme and (b) whether the
scheme would be countered in the impending budget. He also said that it was
vital to him that, for the time that OCL, a third party, was involved, his
£500,000 was protected. He could, in effect, call for it to be repaid and that
right was protected by security.
39.
I find that the main purpose of the 14 day redemption clause was tax
avoidance and in particular to establish that the loan notes were issued at
full value. The scheme was pre-planned and the dramatic drop in value from
£499,500 to £25,000 on day 15 was engineered on the face of the documents. If
this had not been built-in as it was, Mr Bretten would not have been able to
claim that they were issued at full value.
40.
And while I find Mr Bretten was genuinely concerned about whether he
ought to enter into this tax planning at all, and that it suited his concerns
also to have a cooling off period, these concerns were not the main reason for
the 14 day right of redemption at full value. Because, had these concerns been
the primary motivating factor behind those clauses of the document, he could
have protected them more easily by simply delaying entering into the
transactions. He could have waited until he was happy the time was right.
Alternatively, and as he was well aware, he could have implemented the planning
without an opt out as he always had the opt out of simply not claiming the
relief in his tax returns. So gaining an opt out was not Mr Bretten’s main
purpose in including the 14 day redemption clause.
41.
I accept that had the Government actually promulgated tax avoidance
measures which Mr Bretten considered would catch this planning, he may have
exercised this opt out. But I also find that the chance of this was quite
remote. This is because while the Government were quite likely to promulgate
tax avoidance legislation, the chances of it being within the 14 day “cooling
off” period was less likely; and even if the Government did announce it during
those 14 days, Mr Bretten may not have regarded it as impacting on his
planning. Indeed, he did not (and does not) regard Schedule 9A as catching his
planning scheme. And even if he had been less certain of this, he may have
decided to go ahead in any event and simply not claim the tax relief (which in
the event was how he did at first proceed).
42.
Further, I have found that overall the only reason for OCL’s
incorporation into Mr Bretten’s plan to divest himself of assets was to
implement this plan in a tax efficient manner. The only reason for OCL’s
inclusion was tax avoidance; the fact that the involvement of a third party in
the planning meant Mr Bretten needed to ensure the integrity of his £500,000
with the provision by OCL of security does not mean that the purpose of the 14
day redemption clause was anything other than tax planning: on the contrary,
it reinforces the fact that its main purpose was tax avoidance.
43.
In conclusion, the inclusion of the 14 day right of redemption had
considerably more to do with Mr Bretten’s desire to establish that the RDS were
issued at full value than with a desire for a cooling off period. And while he
did regard having a cooling off period as advantageous, Mr Bretten did not
satisfy me that there was any more than a remote possibility it would be
exercised.
Post-implementation
44.
I find the scheme was implemented in the manner expected. Following
implementation, Mr Bretten submitted his self assessment tax return for the
year 02/03 without making a claim for the loss relief he hoped that the
planning entitled him to. On 21 December 2004, however, he amended his return
to claim the loss relief. This was shortly after the publication of the
Tribunal decision in the case of Campbell (discussed below) and
Mr Bretten said that he had waited for the outcome of that case before deciding
whether to make the claim. The taxpayer was successful and Mr Bretten made the
claim.
The legislation
45.
The applicable legislation was agreed between the parties and this was
the provisions (now largely repealed) on relevant discounted securities (“RDS”)
contained in Finance Act 1996 (“FA 96”) Schedule 13 as in force at the time of
the events at issue in this appeal.
Relevant discounted securities legislation
46.
Paragraph 3 of that Schedule provided the definition of an RDS:
“(1) … in this Schedule “relevant discounted
security” means any security which (whenever issued) is such that, taking the
security as at the time of its issue, the amount payable on redemption –
(a) on maturity, or
(b) in the case of a security of which there may be
a redemption before maturity, on at least one of the occasions on which it may
be redeemed,
is or would be an amount involving a deep gain, or
might be an amount which would involve a deep gain….”
47.
Sub-paragraphs (3) & (4) provided the definition of a deep gain as
follows:
“(3) For the purposes of this Schedule the amount
payable on redemption of a security involves a deep gain if –
(a) the issue price is less than the amount so
payable; and
(b) the amount by which it is less represents more
than the relevant percentage of the amount so payable.
(4) In this paragraph “the relevant percentage”, in
relation to an amount payable on redemption of a security means –
(a) the percentage figure equal, in a case where
the period between the date of issue and the date of redemption is less than
thirty years, to one half of the number of years between those dates; and
(b) in any other case, 15 per cent;…..”
48.
The parties were agreed that the six loan notes issued in this case were
relevant discounted securities (“RDS”). As can be seen from the recital of
facts above, the amount payable on redemption on maturity (ie paragraph
3(1)(a)) would involve a deep gain because the amount payable was a 25%
increase on its issue price which was more than the 15% increase specified by
Paragraph 3(4)(b).
49.
The claim to loss relief was based on paragraph 2, taken with paragraphs
4 & 8 of Schedule 13 FA 96. Paragraph 2 provided as follows:
“Paragraph 2
(1) Subject to the following provisions of this
Schedule, where -
(a) a person sustains a loss in any year of
assessment from the discount on a relevant discounted security, and
(b) makes a claim for the purposes of this paragraph
before the end of twelve months from the 31st January next following
that year of assessment,
that person shall be entitled to relief from income
tax on an amount of the claimant’s income for the year equal to the amount of
the loss.
(2) For the purposes of this Schedule a person
sustains a loss from the discount on a relevant discounted security where -
(a) he transfers such a security ….; and
(b) the amount paid by that person in respect of his
acquisition of the security exceeds the amount payable on the transfer….
(3) For the purposes of this Schedule the loss
shall be taken –
(a) to be equal to the amount of the excess increased
by the amount of any relevant costs; and
(b) to be sustained for the purposes of this
Schedule in the year of assessment in which the transfer …. takes place.
…”
50.
It was Mr Bretten’s claim, which was not in dispute, that he
transferred the loan notes when he gifted them to Trust 2. Paragraph 4
provided:
“Paragraph 4
(1) …. In this Schedule references to a transfer,
in relation to a security, are references to any transfer of the security by
way of sale, exchange, gift or otherwise.
….”
51.
It was his case that that transfer by way of gift was to be treated as
taking place at the then market value as he was connected (as settlor) to Trust
2. Paragraph 8 of Schedule 13 provided:
“Paragraph 8
This paragraph applies where a relevant discounted
security is transferred from one person to another and they are connected with
each other.
For the purposes of this Schedule –
(a) the person making the transfer shall be treated
as obtaining in respect of it an amount equal to the market value of the
security at the time of the transfer, and
(b) the person to whom the transfer is made shall
be treated as paying in respect of his acquisition of the security an amount
equal to that market value.
(3) Section 839 of the Taxes Act 1988 (connected
persons) shall apply for the purposes of this paragraph.”
52.
Section 839(3) of the Taxes Act stated that a trustee of a settlement
was connected to the settlor of the settlement. It was not in dispute that Mr
Bretten as settlor was therefore connected to both of the trustees of Trust 2
(himself and Mr Cox). The transfer of the loan notes was a transfer between
connected parties and, it was Mr Bretten’s case, that that transfer was to be
treated as taking place at the then market value. This was not in dispute.
53.
Paragraph 15 of Schedule 13 provided that market value had for these
purposes the same meaning as given in the Taxation of Chargeable Gains Act 1992
(“TCGA”). And s 272 TCGA provided that market value meant “the price which
those assets might reasonably be expected to fetch on a sale in the open
market.” Section 273 gave a further gloss on this definition. So far as
unquoted securities were concerned, the open market was one where “there is
available to any prospective purchaser of the asset in question all the
information which a prudent prospective purchaser of the asset might reasonably
require if he were proposing to purchase [the security] from a willing vendor
by private treaty at arm’s length.”
54.
As stated above there was no dispute between the parties as to the
market value of the six loan notes on the day of the gift of them. At the date
of gift of them to Trust 2 by Mr Bretten the parties were agreed that the total
market value was (or was no more than) £25,000.
55.
An anti-avoidance provision was in inserted into the legislation and
both parties were agreed it was in effect at the relevant time. This provided
as follows:
“Paragraph 9A
(1) Where a relevant discounted security is
transferred by a person (‘the relevant person’) to a person connected with him
and -
(a) the occasion of the relevant person’s
acquisition of the security was its issue to him,
(b) the relevant person was, at the time of issue,
connected with the issuer or……, and
(c) the amount paid by the relevant person in
respect of his acquisition of the security exceeds the market value of the
security at the time of issue,
the relevant person shall be taken for the purposes
of this Schedule not to sustain a loss from the discount on the relevant
discounted security.
56.
Mr Bretten’s submission was that his arrangements were not caught by
this anti-avoidance provision. The RDS were issued to him by OCL which was not
a company to which he was connected. Further, the amount that he paid for the
RDS did not exceed the market value of the RDS at the time of their issue.
Appellant’s case
57.
The appellant’s case was that the statutory provisions have the same
meaning irrespective of the taxpayer’s motive. I do not think HMRC disputed
this.
58.
Applying the legislation to the facts of this case, Mr Bretten says:
·
The loan notes were genuine relevant discounted securities;
·
The loan notes were issued by OCL;
·
Mr Bretten acquired the loan notes and transferred £500,000 of
his own monies to OCL;
·
OCL was a third party to Mr Bretten and would not have issued the
loan notes for any less than £500,000;
·
Mr Bretten transferred the loan notes to Trust 2 and at that
point in time their market value was no more than £25,000.
59.
None of this is disputed by HMRC and therefore, says Mr Bretten, under
the terms of the legislation, he is entitled to the claimed tax relief. Put
simply, the loss arises where “B” is less than “A” as the calculation in
paragraph 2(2) is simply
“A minus B”
where B is the agreed figure of the actual market value
when the RDS were given to Trust 2 (£25,000) and A is (in Mr Bretten’s view)
the amount in exchange for which OCL issued the loan notes (ie £500,000):
£500,000 minus £25,000 = £475,000 loss.
HMRC’s case
60.
HMRC’s case is that based on a purposive construction of the legislation
and a realistic view of the facts, Mr Bretten did not sustain a loss from the
discount on RDSs.
61.
HMRC consider this to be the case because, they say,
(a)
To get within paragraph 2(2)(b) of Schedule 13 Mr Bretten must have
acquired the RDSs. However, say HMRC, Trust 1 was always intended to be substituted
for OCL and Mr Bretten always intended to gift the RDSs to Trust 2. Therefore,
viewing the facts realistically say HMRC, Trust 1 issued the RDSs to Trust 2.
Mr Bretten therefore never acquired the RDSs and is not within paragraph
2(2)(b).
(b)
If HMRC are wrong on this they say that the amount “paid” by Mr Bretten
within the meaning of paragraph 2(2)(b) of Schedule 13 was the value of the
security after expiry of the first 14 days, which was £25,000 which was
equal to their value on gift to Trust 2 and therefore there was no “loss”
within the meaning of that sub-paragraph;
(c)
And if they are wrong on this, HMRC claim that paragraph 9A applies as,
looked at realistically they say, the issuer of the RDSs was Trust 1. Mr
Bretten was connected with Trust 1. As (say HMRC) the RDS was issued at an
undervalue the transfer is therefore deemed not to give rise to a loss.
Statutory construction
62.
The appellant has always admitted that the transactions had a tax
avoidance motive: they were executed in accordance with a plan and, while he
intended to divest himself of £500,000 of assets in any event, he would not
have done so via a convoluted scheme involving loan notes and OCL had it not
been his intention to use his asset protection plan as an opportunity to avoid tax.
63.
It is the appellant’s case that his admitted tax avoidance motive does
not rob the transactions of any effect that they would otherwise have for tax
purposes. The transactions can not be ignored simply because Mr Bretten’s
motive was tax avoidance.
64.
HMRC agree with this in general but consider that in this particular
case the rules of statutory construction mean that the transactions do not have
the tax effect which Mr Brettten claims. And while Mr Bretten agrees, to
paraphrase Ribeiro PJ in the Arrowtown Assets Ltd case [2003] HKCFA 46
at [35], that the statutory provisions must be construed purposively to decide
whether they were intended to apply to the transactions in question viewed
realistically, he considers that there is no scope for a purposive construction
to deny him the claimed relief in this case.
65.
Lewison J in Berry [2011] UKUT 81 recently summarised the
principles of statutory construction in cases where there is an avoidance
motive as follows:
“[31] In my judgment:
(i) the Ramsay principle is a general
principle of statutory construction ….
(ii) The principle is two fold; and it applies to
the interpretation of any statutory provision:
(a) to decide on a purposive construction
exactly what transaction will answer to the statutory description; and
(b) to decide whether the transaction in
question does so …..
(iii) It does not matter in which order these two
steps are taken; and it may be that the whole process is an iterative process
…..
(iv) Although the interpreter should assume that a
statutory provision has some purpose, the purpose must be found in the words of
the statute itself. The court must not infer a purpose without a proper
foundation for doing so…..
(v) In seeking the purpose of a statutory
provision, the interpreter is not confined to a literal interpretation of the
words, but must have regard to the context and scheme of the relevant Act as a
whole…..
(vi) However, the more comprehensively Parliament
sets out the scope of a statutory provision or description, the less room there
will be for an appeal to a purpose which is not the literal meaning of the
words ….
(vii) In looking at particular words that Parliament
uses what the interpreter is looking for is the relevant fiscal concept….
(viii) Although one cannot classify all concepts a
priori as ‘commercial’ or ‘legal’, it is not an unreasonable generalisation to
say that if Parliament refers to some commercial concept such as a gain or loss
it is likely to mean a real gain or a real loss rather than one that is illusory
in the sense of not changing the overall economic position of the parties to a
transaction……
(ix) A provision granting relief from tax is
generally (though not universally) to be taken to refer to transactions
undertaken for a commercial purpose and not solely for the purpose of complying
with the statutory requirements of tax relief…..However, even if a transaction
is carried out in order to avoid tax it may still be one that answers to the
statutory description….In other words, tax avoidance schemes sometimes work.
(x) In approaching the factual question whether the
transaction in question answers the statutory description the facts must be
viewed realistically …..
(xi) A realistic view of the facts includes looking
at the overall effect of a composite transaction, rather than considering each
step individually….
(xii) A series of transactions may be viewed as a
composite transaction where the series of transactions is expected to be
carried through as a whole, either because there is an obligation to do so, or
because there is an expectation that they will be carried through as a whole
and no likelihood in practice that they will not…..
(xiii) In considering the facts the fact-finding
tribunal should not be distracted by any peripheral steps inserted by the
actors that are in fact irrelevant to the way in which the scheme was intended
to operate….
(xiv) In considering whether there is no practical
likelihood that the whole series of transactions will be carried out, it is
legitimate to ignore commercially irrelevant contingencies and to consider it
without regards to the possibility that, contrary to the intention and
expectation of the parties it might not work as planned….Even if the
contingency is a real commercial possibility it may be disregarded if the
parties proceeded on the basis that it should be disregarded…..”
66.
This interpretation of the many authorities on purposive construction of
tax legislation is, of course, binding on this Tribunal. In any event, neither
party suggested that it was not right. The difference between the parties is
how the principles should properly be applied in this case.
Interpreting the statute purposively
67.
Mr Bretten sees the statute as imposing an “A minus B” test where the
figure for A is £500,000 and the figure for B is £25,000, resulting in a loss
of £475,000. HMRC consider there is scope for a less mechanistic construction
of paragraph 2(2)(b) of Schedule 13. In particular, HMRC see this as the sort
of provision envisaged by Mr Justice Lewison in Berry at (viii) above
where he referred to the statute using a commercial concept involving a “real
loss rather than one that is illusory in the sense of not changing the overall
economic position of the parties to a transaction……”
Mayes
68.
When the Court of Appeal looked at very different legislation in the
case of Mayes [2011] EWCA Civ 407, they concluded that that legislation
had to be applied mechanistically and there was no scope for considering
whether there was a real commercial gain. In that case, the legislation
referred to something being “treated as a gain”, and the Court found these very
words implied that the gain might not be a real gain at all. Toulson LJ said of
the legislation under consideration in that case:
“[102] ….[the legislation in question] creates a
complex set of rules for determining when a gain is to be treated as arising in
connection with a life insurance policy.
[103] Inherent in the scheme is the possibility of
a disconnection between what would be regarded as a gain on an ordinary commercial
view and what is to be treated as a gain for the purposes of the statute.
[104] In some cases, a taxpayer may be liable for a
gain which the statute requires him to be treated as having made, although the
chargeable event giving rise to the deemed gain has no caused him to make an
equivalent gain in real terms.
[105] In the present case the opposite has
occurred….”
69.
But so far as the RDS legislation in Schedule 13 was concerned, the
Court of Appeal has not applied a mechanistic approach. In Astell & Edwards
[2009] EWCA 1010 it clearly considered Schedule 13 to be legislation where
Parliament intended the reality of the transaction to be considered. Unlike
the legislation in Mayes, Schedule 13 does not refer to something being
treated as a loss or a gain.
Astell
70.
Although Astell involved the same provisions as this case, the
scheme was very different. In Mr Bretten’s case, there was no intention for
the RDS to be redeemed before it has run its full term: but in Astell (at
least in so far as Mr Edwards was concerned) the scheme involved the early
redemption of the security at a loss. The Tribunal found as a fact that so far
as Mr Astell was concerned there was real uncertainty whether the security
would be redeemed before it had reached full term.
71.
There were two aspects to the Astell case. Firstly, there was
the question whether the security issued to Mr Edwards was an RDS because there
was no real likelihood of it going to full term and therefore being redeemed at
a gain. The Court held that:
“[46]….it is implicit in the statutory purpose that
the agreed terms which might cause a deep gain to arise have to have a reality
beyond the printed page….”
72.
In other words, the security issued to Mr Edwards was not, under
paragraph 3, an RDS, because, seen as a preordained series of transactions, or
a single multi-facted transaction, there was no real possibility that the
security would ever be redeemed at a gain.
73.
The second aspect was whether the securities (identical in terms)
actually involved a “deep gain” as defined because in both cases the “gain”
could only realistically be paid by the issuers of the security (which were
trusts set up by the taxpayers and of which they were the main beneficiaries)
out of capital provided to the trusts by the taxpayers. In other words, were
the securities to be redeemed at full term, the money would go around in a
circle: the gain would only be realised by the taxpayers because they had
earlier given the trusts the funds to pay it.
74.
The Court held that:
“[61]….The question was whether on the facts the
terms of redemption resulted in a redemption at a deep gain for the purposes of
paragraph 3 of Schedule 13….
[62]…the court is entitled…to have regard to the
full sequence of the transaction….Accordingly, the court can take into account
the fact that the appellants are no better off under the transaction if the
right of early redemption is exercised. They therefore made no overall
gain…..”
75.
The issues in the case were therefore different to those in this case.
It is accepted that the security in this case was a relevant discounted
security. This was not accepted in Astell and the Court agreed with
HMRC that the securities in that case were not RDSs.
76.
What is relevant is that the Court of Appeal interpreted paragraph 3 of
schedule 13 as involving what I will describe as a “real” deep gain. It was
not a “real” deep gain if either there was no realistic prospect of the RDS
being realised or if it was not, realistically speaking, a gain at all, because
the money went around in a circle. The taxpayers lost their appeal.
77.
It is a short leap of logic from Astell to say that if paragraph
3 of Schedule 13 involves only “real” deep gains, then paragraph 2 of the same
schedule involves only “real” losses. There must be a realistic prospect of a
loss being realised and there must, realistically speaking, be a loss. Is it
right to make this leap of logic? The meaning of paragraph 2(2)(b) itself was
considered by tribunals in two cases, Campbell [2004] STC (SCD)
396 and Audley [2011] SFTD 597.
Campbell
78.
The case of Campbell concerned a subscription to a company
owned and controlled by the taxpayer in return for the issue of RDS at an
overvalue. The RDS were then given away to the taxpayer’s wife so that the
transfer value (or the “B” in the calculation “A minus B”) was the market value
on the date of transfer, as in this case. The taxpayer had an independent
purpose in subscribing for the RDS in that he wished to put his company in
funds for the purpose of its business.
79.
It was put to the Special Commissioners in Campbell that “loss”
in the RDS provisions was a legal concept rather than a commercial one and
therefore not susceptible to purposive interpretation. The Special
Commissioners did not necessarily accept this but what they did say was this:
“[87] Once an amount paid in respect of a relevant
discounted security is ascertained and the amount received (or deemed to be
received) on transfer or redemption is determined, there is a ‘loss’ where the
former exceeds the latter. There is no room for the purpose of the holder of
the relevant discounted security to inform the construction of the term
‘loss’…..”
80.
So in the view of the Special Commissioners, “loss” does not have a real
meaning in this context. Is that right? It is difficult to reconcile with the
Court of Appeal’s decision in Astell. “Deep gain” also had a
mechanistic meaning in the sense of “A is less than B”. In paragraph 3(3) it
is stated to be:
“..the amount payable on redemption of a security
involves a deep gain if – (a) the issue price is less than the amount so
payable….”
81.
Compare this to the “A minus B” meaning of loss in paragraph 2(2):
“…a person sustains a loss…where – (a) he transfers
such a security ….and (b) the amount paid by that person in respect of his acquisition
of the security exceeds the amount payable on the transfer or redemption”
82.
Campbell was decided before Astell and without the
benefit of it. The Court of Appeal in Astell itself made no comment on
the rightness or otherwise of the decision: it was, after all, not
directly in point. Campbell was, however, considered by the Upper
Tribunal in Berry.
83.
Berry concerned a slightly different taxation provision
and very different facts. It involved gilt strips which were sold by the
taxpayer on a forward contract (the consideration “x” was payable at a future
date) with an immediate grant back, for consideration of “y” paid to the
taxpayer, of an option to repurchase the gilt strips for “x – y”. In other
words, the transaction was in effect self-cancelling. The taxpayer claimed a
loss because he paid “x” but only received “x-y”, but there was no real loss as
he had already been paid the “y” when he granted the option.
84.
The relevant law was paragraph 14A(3) of Schedule 13, a provision which
replaced paragraph 2. As with this case, and the Campbell case,
the Berry case turned on whether there was a loss. The provision
dealing with this provided:
Paragraph 14A (3)
“For the purposes of this paragraph a person
sustains a loss from the discount on a strip where –
(a) he transfers the strip or becomes entitled, as
the person holding it, to any payment on its redemption; and
(b) the amount paid by him for the strip exceeds the
amount payable on the transfer or redemption…
The loss shall be taken to be equal to the amount of
the excess…..”
85.
While not identical, this is similar to the mechanistic calculation of
loss on an RDS under paragraph 2 of Schedule 13 in the sense it is “A minus B =
loss”. Lewison J said:
“…in Astell…Arden LJ rejected the submission
that a purposive construction should not be applied to paras 1, 2, and 3 of Sch
13. Paragraph 14A is the replacement of para 2, and is expressed in much the
same terms, so the same principle must apply. If and in so far as the Special
Commissioners held otherwise in Campbell…I should follow the Court of
Appeal by whose decision I am bound. I therefore reject the submission that
the Ramsay principle is to be disapplied in interpreting para 14A.”
86.
However, he then went on to consider whether, even applying Ramsay,
there was no room for a “real” loss because the statute was prescriptive on how
the loss was calculated. He considered the Campbell case in
detail. He said that properly understood, the Tribunal had not said that the
reality of the situation should be ignored: the reality was that Mr Campbell
had suffered a loss as he had borrowed the money to buy the loan notes and then
given the loan notes to his wife. He said Campbell was properly
distinguished from Berry because in Campbell it had
been conceded by HMRC that the loan notes were not subscribed at
undervalue.
87.
Mr Justice Lewison upheld the FTT’s decision against the taxpayer. He
said a realistic view of the facts was that the option fee was no more than a
refundable deposit and it was a self-cancelling scheme with no loss being
realised. So far as paragraph 14A was concerned he held:
“[51] As I have said, the FTT held that the purpose
of para 14A was the general proposition stated in sub-para (1) viz:
‘A
person who sustains a loss in the year of assessment from the discount on a
strip shall be entitled to relief from income tax on the amount of his income
for that year according to the amount of the loss.’
[52] In my judgment the FTT were right to identify
the purpose of the paragraph in that way. This is not a case in which
Parliament has used algebra (amount A and B) to create a notional profit or
loss. It has used words which have a recognised commercial meaning; and it is
to be expected that Parliament intended to tax (or relieve) real commercial
outcomes. The FTT were right not to adopt a slavishly literal ‘tick-box’
interpretation of the legislation. This is precisely how the Ramsay principle
is meant to operate. I thus conclude that the FTT made no error of law in
identifying the purpose of the legislation.”
88.
I agree with HMRC that Mr Justice Lewison’s view of Campbell is
that the case might well have had a different outcome if HMRC had not conceded
the loan notes were issued at full value. I also agree that Campbell is
distinguishable from this case as the Special Commissioners found that
subscription to the company had a real commercial purpose. That is clearly not
the case here where it is conceded OCL’s involvement served no commercial
purpose.
Summary
89.
In summary, where the intention of Parliament is only to tax real gains,
then the courts and tribunals are free only to recognise real losses.
90.
I find that Campbell is not authority that paragraph 2(2)
should be given a mechanistic interpretation: in so far as that was the basis
of the decision, it was wrongly decided (see the citation from Berry above). However, Mr Justice Lewison considered that the case was
correctly decided. As both the Court of Appeal in Astell and the Upper
Tribunal in Berry decided that provisions related to and very similar to
paragraph 2(2) were intended to apply to commercial reality, the explanation
for this view is that the formula “A minus B” must be applied mechanistically,
as it was in Campbell, once the figures for “A” and “B” are known, but
the calculation of “A”, at least, and perhaps “B”, must be consistent with
commercial reality. The calculation must have been intended to give effect to
the notion of a “real” loss envisaged by Parliament when it legislated the
phrase “…a person sustains a loss…”
91.
Is it right that Campbel lis to be distinguished solely
because HMRC conceded the figures for “A” and “B”, and would the outcome the
case have been different if they had not? Mr Justice Lewison did refer to the
fact (see paragraph 86 above) that the taxpayer in Campbell made
a “real” loss in the sense he was worse off after the planned series of
transactions than he was before. Is this also a point of distinction?
92.
I think not. The logic of a loss being a “real” loss is that it can’t
have been a loss that was intended to arise. If a party intends to give away
some of his assets, the act of giving away is not a commercial loss as it is
intentional. The situation of a taxpayer choosing to give away assets as part
of tax avoidance scheme arose in the recent FTT case of Audley.
93.
As part of a tax avoidance scheme, the taxpayer gave away his home with
a true value of £1.8million plus £250,000 in cash to a family trust. The
trustees issued to him RDS in return with a face value of £2,050,000. Because
of the terms of the RDS, for instance that it was only repayable in 60 years,
the value of the RDS at date of issue was only £35,700. A few days later, and
in accordance with the pre-planned scheme, the taxpayer gave the RDS to a second
family trust.
94.
The taxpayer claimed a loss on the basis that A = £2.050,000 and B =
£35,700 so that “A minus B” left him with a loss of £2,014,300 for the purpose
of paragraph 2(2)(b). The Tribunal dismissed his appeal against HMRC’s refusal
of the loss relief, holding that what the taxpayer paid for the loan
note was its true value (£35,700) and the excess was given as a gift to the
first family trust:
“[88]…This was not a subscription of £2.05m for a
loan note issued by the trustees of a family trust; rather it was a gift of the
house and a significant amount of cash to the trustees….The only thing obtained
in return was the loan note which had a market value of £35,700.
[89] ….To the extent that any amount can be said to
have been paid for the acquisition of the loan note, it is limited to the true
value of the loan note when issued: £35,700.”
95.
I consider that this case was correctly decided in line with Astell and
Berry. It is implicit in the decision that it was irrelevant
that the taxpayer was worse off after the planning that before it: before the
planning was executed he owned a house and some cash. After it was executed,
he only possessed a life interest in the house and cash. That this “real”
decrease in assets is irrelevant to the question of whether there has been a
real loss has to be right for a number of reasons.
96.
Firstly, it is planned. It is part of the planning scheme. It does not
arise by chance. It is implicit in the RDS legislation that Parliament
envisaged that an RDS involved risk: a deep gain might arise or it might not.
The “loss” envisaged by Parliament in paragraph 2 was not one that was intended
to arise from the outset. A planned loss is not a commercial loss: commerce
involves an intention to make a profit and a risk that the intention won’t be
realised.
97.
Secondly, Parliament intended the loss in paragraph 2(2) to be “A minus
B”. Whereas the decrease in the value of the taxpayer’s assets in Audley in
no way matched the “A minus B” and therefore that decrease in the value of the
taxpayer’s assets was not the “loss” intended by Parliament.
98.
Audley suggests, and I consider, that the only proper
distinction with Campbell is that HMRC (mistakenly) conceded the value
of “A” in that case.
Pike
99.
A similar view to the decision in Audley was expressed obiter (by
myself and Mr Thomas), without the benefit of argument, in the case of Pike [2011] UKFTT 289 (TC):
“[91]Mr Pike gave £6m to the company and in return
he got a security with a face value of £6m. But he did this knowing that in
return he would get an asst worth approximately £2.5m. This was not a case of
making a bad bargain: Mr Pike did not pay £6m hoping it was worth £6m or
more. It was an integral part of the tax avoidance scheme that the security
was in fact wroth considerably less than this and the scheme could not have
worked if Mr Pike had paid what the security was actually worth.
…
[93] We have not had the benefit of submissions on
this point and it is not necessary for our decision, but we express the
preliminary view that it may be that Mr Pike paid what the security was
worth (approximately £2.5m) for the purposes of para 2(2). The rest of the £6m
was to capitalise his wholly owned company and was not actually paid for
the security…..”
100. As can been
seen, Pike was on the facts virtually indistinguishable from the facts
in the case of Campbell. However, following Berry and
Astell, Campbell has to be seen as decided on the basis
that HMRC had conceded that the acquisition price of the RDS was its face value
rather than market value, and on the facts of the case HMRC were ill-advised to
make that concession.
101. Unlike Audley,
the taxpayer in Pike did not suffer any decrease in the value of
assets when the RDS was issued: as with the taxpayer in Campbell, he
paid an excessive price for the RDS and effectively gave away money to his
wholly owned company. In such a case, in reality, the donor or subscriber has
not given away assets at all, but simply swopped cash for a different type of
asset (a more valuable wholly owned company). There was of course a further
decrease in the value of the taxpayer’s assets when he made the later, planned,
gift of the RDSs to a family trust. But as I have already said, I do not
consider that this can be seen as a loss as it was a planned gift.
Summary
102. After this
survey of the authorities, I find that “loss” in the RDS legislation and in
particular in paragraph 2 refers to a “real” loss and that therefore to the
extent that paragraph 2(2)(b) requires a mechanistic A minus B calculation, the
figures used for A & B must be realistic figures, so that the amount “paid”
is viewed realistically and a “real” loss is calculated. Further, Campbell is to be distinguished because HMRC conceded the figure for “A” and
not because it involved any real loss, even though it did involve a decrease in
the real value of the taxpayer’s assets because he gave away an asset to a
family trust. This decrease in the real value of the taxpayer’s assets was
also true in Audley and Pike, but I consider it irrelevant
because it was part of the planning scheme. A planned loss is not a real loss
as envisaged by Parliament in paragraph 2.
Real commercial purpose
103. Campbell, Pike, Audley and this case all involve a situation where the
reality is that, at least on one level, the taxpayer is worse off after
the series of transactions is executed than before. These were not self
cancelling transactions as in the Berry case. They all involved
situations where the taxpayer had a real commercial purpose other than tax
avoidance, in divesting themselves of assets.
104. In Campbell and
Pike the taxpayers wished to capitalise their companies. They could
have achieved this purpose by subscribing for share capital. They chose
instead to purchase RDSs (at an undervalue) solely for tax avoidance reasons.
In Audley the taxpayer appeared, at least, to have a genuine,
altruistic, intention to give away capital to his family although, since he was
the income beneficiary and trustee, largely the transaction was self
cancelling.
105. Does having a
real commercial purpose, or at least a purpose other than tax avoidance make a
difference? It is difficult to see why it would make any difference at all in
the sense that, whatever the ultimate purpose was, the only purpose to the
issue of the RDS was tax avoidance. And anyway, properly the question is not
the taxpayer’s motive and whether there is a real commercial purpose. The
question is whether the legislation purposively interpreted was intended by
Parliament to apply to the transactions viewed realistically. Paragraph 2 of
Schedule 13 was intended to apply to real losses: whether or not there was a
non-tax avoidance motive to the achievement of the end result (such as
capitalising a company) rather than the transactions being self cancelling (as
in Berry) makes no difference if the subscription for the RDS was
at an intentional undervalue.
Viewing the facts realistically
106. Having
interpreted the legislation, I need now to view the facts of Mr Bretten’s case
realistically. I have moved on to point (x) in Mr Justice Lewison’s summary of
what might be called the Ramsay line of authorities.
In approaching the factual question whether the
transaction in question answers the statutory description the facts must be
viewed realistically …..
(xi) A realistic view of the facts includes looking
at the overall effect of a composite transaction, rather than considering each
step individually….
(xii) A series of transactions may be viewed as a
composite transaction where the series of transactions is expected to be
carried through as a whole, either because there is an obligation to do so, or
because there is an expectation that they will be carried through as a whole
and no likelihood in practice that they will not…..
A series of transactions?
107. Point (xi)
requires the Tribunal to look at the overall effect of a composite transactions
so I first have to determine whether the facts involved a composite
transaction, and what that composite transaction comprised, and what was its
overall effect.
108. Looking at
(xii), a composite transaction is a series of transactions where there was
either an obligation to carry out the various steps or it was merely expected
that the series would be carried out and no real likelihood that they
would not be.
109. There was no obligation
on Mr Bretten to substitute Trust 1 as issuer of the loan notes, nor to gift
the loan notes to Trust 2. In that sense it was not a series of transactions.
Mr Bretten’s point was that he was not bound to nor was he under any
obligation to dispose of the loan notes.
110. While I accept
Mr Bretten was not obliged to carry out the steps in this transaction, it is
still a series of transaction if the various steps were expected to be carried
with no real likelihood that they would not be carried out.
111. It is not in
dispute that before the expiry of the first 14 days, Mr Bretten would either
have caused Trust 1 to be substituted as creditor or exercised his right
to redeem the loan notes. This has to be right as otherwise Mr Bretten would
in effect have given £500,000 to OCL and it was no part of his plan to give
away half a million pounds to an unconnected third party.
112. Further, once
the 14 days had passed, I find there was no real likelihood that the
transactions would not proceed and in particular no real likelihood that the
gift to Trust 2 by Mr Bretten would not take place. This was because the
entire objective of using RDS was tax avoidance, and once the scheme was put in
motion there was no real likelihood Mr Bretten would not see it through to the
end. While he might have got cold feet, this was only remote possibility and
in any event he would have done what he did, which was to complete the series
of transactions and then consider whether or not he wanted to claim the relief
in his tax return.
113. There were other
elements of uncertainty. Clause 5, outlined, above, would have put an end to
the planned series of transactions if the chance inbuilt into that clause (of
the FTSE 100 index reaching 4000) had come to pass. Mr Bretten did not rely on
this clause in the hearing. I consider this a concession well made. As Mr
Justice Lewison said at (xiv) unlikely contingencies inserted to introduce an
element of chance should be ignored and even where the contingency is “a real
commercial possibility it may be disregarded if the parties proceeded on the
basis that it should be disregarded…..” So far as clause 5 is concerned, both
parties are agreed it could be ignored. Had this not been conceded I would find
that it ought to be ignored as Mr Bretten’s evidence was that clause 5 was
inserted solely as a sort of window dressing to make the scheme look better but
with no real expectation that the uncertain event would ever occur to disrail
the planning scheme.
The first 14 days
114. The critical
difference between the parties is how the first 14 days should be viewed. I
have already found as a fact (see 42-43) that the main purpose of the right to
redeem at face value for the first 14 days was to bolster the tax avoidance
scheme. It was only a remote possibility that it would ever be exercised.
115. HMRC’s view is
that from moment of issue to OCL always intended that scheme would be followed
through and although there was a possibility of redemption this was not
intended or expected and cite Scottish Provident Society [2004] UKHL 52
where Lord Nicholls said:
“[23] We think it would destroy the value of the Ramsay
principle of construing provisions…if [the] composite effect [of composite
transactions] had to be disregarded simply because the parties had deliberately
included a commercially irrelevant contingency, creating an acceptable risk
that the scheme might not work as planned. We would be backing the world of
artificial tax schemes, now equipped with anti-Ramsay devices. The
composite effect of such a scheme should be considered as it was intended to
operate and without regard to the possibility that, contrary to the intention
and expectations of the parties, it might not work as planned.”
116. I agree with
HMRC’s view, and therefore, so far as the test in (xii) is concerned, I find
that there a series of transactions which included the initial creation of the
loan notes by OCL, incorporated the substitution of Trust 1 as debtor and did
not come to an end until after Mr Bretten gifted the loan notes to Trust 2.
This was the scheme envisaged by Mr Bretten, by OCL and by Mr Harris. It was
executed as expected, and while Mr Bretten had a real choice in the first 14
days to redeem the loan notes and bring the scheme to an end, for the reasons
given I above I find there was no real likelihood that this would happen.
117. Further, even if
I thought as a matter of fact the first 14 days did involve a real likelihood
that Mr Bretten would chose to redeem the loan notes and bring the scheme to a
premature end, I would still consider that there was a planned series of
transactions from the moment the loan notes were issued.
118. This is because
the right of redemption (in so far as it can be seen as a right that would
actually be exercised rather than a right that existed simply to establish a
high value for the RDS) did not more than give Mr Bretten the chance to change
his mind and unwind the scheme.
119. Mr Justice
Lewison did not explicitly consider what might be described as a “cooling off
clause” at his paragraphs (x) – (xvi) above (my paragraph 65). Rather, he was
considering clauses such as the clause 5 where the element of uncertainty was
something outside the control of the parties. I do not think that he meant the
question whether there is “no real likelihood” of it coming to pass as the
right test to apply where it is within the control of the tax avoider and
amounts to no more than an option to unwind the planning. In any planning,
there is always the possibility, whether express on the terms or not, of the
tax avoider deciding not to go through with the scheme and unwinding it after
it has commenced (although sometimes to do so might require the cooperation of
a third party). Logically, this ability to unwind it can not mean that the
scheme is any less than a planned series of transactions. So even where the
right to unwind the planning is express, and because it was agreed in advance
and involves no cooperation from any other party in order to execute it, it
should make no difference to the assessment of the scheme as a planned series
of transactions: whether the scheme is a series of transactions cannot depend
on an assessment of the state of the tax avoider’s nerves and in particular how
likely he was to develop cold feet.
120. Therefore, in my
view, the existence of such an opt out should be entirely discounted when
considering whether there was a composite transaction.
121. Another way of
looking at it is that the planned series of transactions includes any
preliminary scene setting without which the planning would not work as intended.
For instance, as Mr Bretten said, he would not have paid £500,000 to OCL at the
time OCL issued the loan notes unless OCL had first given to Trust 1 the option
for Trust 1 to elect to substitute itself as debtor. Yet at the time of the
grant of the option, Mr Bretten clearly was not committed to seeing the
planning through to its intended end. But the option was nevertheless an
integral part of the planning. Mr Bretten could have opted out of the planning
after the option was granted but before the RDS were issued.
This does not make the grant of the option any less a part of the composite
transaction. So the fact he could have opted out at any time during the first
14 days after the loan notes were actually issued does not mean that the issue
of the loan notes was any less an integral part of the planning scheme.
122. So I find that
there was a series of transactions from the moment OCL issued the option to
Trust 1, through the issue of the loan notes to Mr Brettten, including the
substitutes of Trust 1 as debtor, and finally including the gift of the loan
notes to Trust 2.
123. Having viewed
the facts realistically I move on to consider HMRC’s case. I look at HMRC’s
second argument first, as this is closest to existing case law.
Conclusions
HMRC’s second argument
124. HMRC’s second
argument, if it failed on its argument that Mr Bretten did not really acquire
the RDSs, is that that the amount “paid” by Mr Bretten within the meaning of
paragraph 2(2)(b) of Schedule 13 was the value of the security after expiry
of the first 14 days, which was £25,000, which was equal to the value of the
RDS on gift to Trust 2, and that therefore there was no “loss” within the
meaning of that sub-paragraph.
125. Here the
question is what is the amount Mr Bretten “paid …in respect of his acquisition
of the security…..” This is the figure of “A” in the sum “A minus B”.
126. And as I have
said in paragraph 102, the word “paid” means what was really paid for the
RDSs. Mr Bretten emphasised that £500,000 was really paid: £500,000 left his
bank account and arrived in that of OCL’s. And I am quite satisfied that the
deal with OCL was at full value. For its first 14 days the loan notes would
really have been worth a figure approaching half a million pounds (as explained
above in paragraph 20 they would not have been worth quite this figure). OCL
would certainly not have issued the loan notes for any less than £500,000. Mr
Bretten and OCL traded at arm’s length.
127. But as I have
said, the legislation lends itself to a purposive interpretation and the question
is what Mr Bretten really paid for the loan notes; and to decide that I am
entitled to look at the facts realistically. Realistically, a series of
transactions was intended and expected to take place. It was intended and
expected that in 14 days’ time the loan notes would radically decrease in value
(because the right of early redemption at issue price would expire) but before
that happened Trust 1 would be the debtor (and in effect the beneficiary of the
huge decrease in value of the loan notes). Realistically speaking, I agree
with HMRC, Mr Bretten only paid £25,000 to acquire these loan notes
because he knew and intended that when he paid £500,000 that 14 days later they
would only be worth £25,000, and he intended Trust 1 to be the debtor on the
loan notes immediately before the devaluation took place. I find that viewing
the planned transactions as a whole, Mr Bretten gave away £475,000 to
Trust 1 and only paid only £25,000 for the loan notes.
128. Put it another
way, HMRC’s case is that it was a series of transactions planned and which was
executed as intended from the moment OCL issued the option to Trust 1. As it
was part of the plan that at Day 15 the RDS would suffer a radical decrease in
value, on a realistic view of the facts, taking into account that the decrease
in value was planned, Mr Bretten should be seen as having only paid at Day 1
the £25,000 the RDS were worth on and after Day 15, and as in effect to have
given away the remainder of the £500,000 to a family trust. Because that was
the effect of the planned series of transactions.
129. Viewed
realistically, there was no chance whatsoever that (unless the scheme was
collapsed by early redemption) the substitution option would not be exercised.
Viewed realistically there was absolutely no chance of Mr Bretten realising a
“real” loss vis-à-vis OCL: there was never any chance that OCL would be left
holding the £500,000 and Mr Bretten left with notes worth a mere £25,000. We
have said the possibility of early redemption was remote and did not happen and
should be ignored. Had it been exercised, no loss would have been sustained
(or only a minimal loss of £500). Viewed realistically Mr Bretten did what he
intended: he gave £500,000 to family trusts. He intended a gift to Trust 1 of
£475,000, and this is in effect what he achieved in a roundabout fashion via
OCL and a 15 day delay.
130. Therefore,
mechanistically A minus B is £25,000 minus £25,000. Mr Bretten’s loss was
nil. HMRC were correct to disallow his claim for a loss. That is sufficient to
dispose of the appeal but I have further comments to make.
131. I have already
dealt with the 14 day right to redeem the loan notes for issue price or nearly
issue price. I have said it should be disregarded as a remote contingency
and/or because opt outs should be ignored when assessing whether there is a
composite transaction. Therefore, the whole scheme, from the grant of the
option by OCL to Trust 1 through to the gift by Mr Bretten to Trust 2, should
be seen as a single composite transaction.
132. My comment is
that even if I am wrong on this, I do not see it as being of any help to Mr
Bretten. If there was a realistic chance that once the RDS were issued they
would be redeemed without the scheme being seen through as planned, then again
the question would be, viewing the facts realistically, what has Mr Bretten
“paid …in respect of his acquisition of the security…..” ? In this scenario,
realistically speaking, Mr Bretten did not really acquire the RDS until he lost
the right to cancel them. If the 15 days should be seen as a cooling off
period, in which Mr Bretten was uncertain whether to proceed with his plan or
not, then viewed realistically the cooling off period was like an option. He
was not committed the transaction until his right (or the right of the intended
new owner, Trust 2) to cancel the RDS expired. And that only happened on Day
15. And at that point the RDS were, as planned, worth only £25,000. So even on
this view, Mr Bretten only paid £25,000 to acquire the RDS.
133. In other words,
incorporating the 14 day rights to redemption and inserting a third party
(OCL), while it distinguishes this case from others that have gone before, such
as Audley, fails to save the scheme. There was never any intention or
expectation that OCL would ever benefit from the scheme to a greater extent
than £500. It was always intended that the loan notes’ value would decrease to
£25,000 on day 15. OCL and the 15 day redemption plus security were just steps
inserted into the transaction which resulted in an artificially inflated value
for a limited period.
134. Further, as I
have also already said, an intentional gift cannot be equated with a loss. Mr
Bretten intended to give away £500,000 to family. And the effect of his
complicated scheme is that that is what he achieved. He entered into a
scheme that resulted in Trust 1 having a “gift” of £475,000 (in that it
received £500,000 for assuming the role of debtor to the loan notes, but the
value of the loan decreased to £25,000 shortly after it assumed the role of debtor).
And he gave the loan notes (now worth £25,000) to Trust 2. In total he gave
away £500,000, as planned, to his family. An intentional gift is not a loss
within the meaning of paragraph 2(2). If and to the extent Campbell suggests
otherwise I do not agree with it: I prefer the decision in Audley.
135. Similarly, the
fact Mr Bretten’s intention to give away £500,000 to his family was a genuine
desire borne out of commercial considerations and uninfluenced by tax, does not
save the scheme. As I have already said, the question is whether the facts
viewed realistically answer the statutory description. “Loss” refers to a real
loss. While Mr Bretten’s gift was entirely genuine and reasonable, a planned
gift is not a commercial loss and was not intended by Parliament to be relieved
by the provisions of Schedule 13.
HMRC’s first argument
136. I have already
dismissed the appeal but for the sake of completeness I express my findings on
HMRC’s other arguments.
137. HMRC’s first
argument is that to get within paragraph 2(2)(b) of Schedule 13 Mr Bretten must
have acquired the RDS. However, say HMRC, Trust 1 was always intended to be
substituted for OCL and Mr Bretten always intended to gift the RDS to Trust 2.
Therefore, viewing the facts realistically, say HMRC, Trust 1 issued the RDS to
Trust 2. Mr Bretten, therefore say HMRC, never acquired the RDS and he is not
within paragraph 2(2)(b) which required him to have paid an amount “in respect
of his acquisition of the security”.
138. In other words,
HMRC’s case is that the issue by OCL should be ignored and Trust 1 should be
treated as the issuer. The purchase by Mr Bretten should also be ignored and
Trust 2 should be treated as the noteholder from the start. Thus Mr Bretten’s
asset protection scheme worked as intended but the tax avoidance scheme failed
as
139. steps inserted
solely with a tax avoidance motive should be ignored.
140. This argument
seems a radical interpretation and I bear in mind that the doctrine in Ramsay
etc is not a licence to disregard steps inserted solely with a tax avoidance
motive (see paragraph [78] in Mayes and also paragraphs [36-37] of Barclays
Mercantile v Mawson [2004] UKHL 51). One must look at the
legislation and ask if the transaction viewed realistically answers the
statutory description.
141. Mr Bretten wants
me to look at each transaction individually and maintains that I cannot
disregard the fact that the loan notes were actually issued by OCL and issued
to him. But as set out above, there was a series of transactions here and, as
Mr Justice Berry said at (xi) above “[a] realistic view of the facts includes
looking at the overall effect of a composite transaction, rather than
considering each step individually….” I find that the effect of the series of
transactions, or the single composite transaction, was to leave Trust 2 as the
noteholder. This was intended from the start.
142. Is it right to
say, therefore, that Mr Bretten never acquired the security or that he acquired
it on behalf of Trust 2? Ramsay, Berry, Astell and other cases looked
at what Parliament really intended by its reference to gains and losses, so I
must consider what Parliament really intended by “acquisition”. As those cases
decided that Parliament intended to refer to “real” gains and losses it is a
short leap of logic to say Parliament also intended to refer to a “real”
acquisition.
143. Mr Bretten
agrees that I must give “acquisition” a purposive interpretation. His view
is that by “acquisition” Parliament meant that he became the legal and
beneficial owner of the RDSs. He suggests that he would not have acquired the
RDSs if he had only become the legal owner, holding the shares on behalf of
Trust 2, or restricted in what he could do with them. But as a matter of fact
this was not the case: on the issue of them to him, he became the legal and
beneficial owner of the RDSs, and could do what he liked with them. Although
he did deal with them in accordance with his pre-determined plan, he had the
option to change his mind at any time.
144. I have already
said that in the legislation there is implicit the element of chance: there
must be a chance of a real deep gain and the chance of a real loss. Even if
the terms of the RDS were a guaranteed deep gain on maturity, implicit in the
legislation is the assumption that the holder of the RDS is at risk and might
nevertheless realise a loss (perhaps because of a default). The legislation
was not contemplating a situation where the noteholder’s entire period of
ownership from the moment of acquisition, including the exact terms of his disposal
of the RDS, would proceed accordingly to a plan laid out in advance. Where
there is such a plan, it seems to me that the person to whom the RDS is issued
does not “acquire” the RDS in the sense intended by Parliament of taking on the
risk of changes in value inherent in ownership of an RDS. Such a person does
not acquire the RDS in order to deal with it freely as a true owner would.
145. Mr Bretten
points out that he had free will and he did not have to proceed in accordance
with his pre-determined plan: he chose to do so. But on authority, including
that of Berry, when looking at the facts realistically, I should
ignore the possibility that the plan might not be carried out if there was an
expectation it would be and no likelihood it would not be carried out (point
(xii) of Berry). As I have already said, the chance of the scheme in
this case not being carried through was remote.
146. So, as this was
a case where I should view the facts as if Mr Bretten had no free will because,
in reality what he would do with the RDSs was already determined before he
acquired them, I find Mr Bretten, although he became the owner of the RDS for
some 9 days, did not “acquire” the RDS in the sense intended by Parliament
because he did not in effect have the full rights of an owner nor did he take
on the risk inherent in ownership of an RDS of a change in value.
147. So there was no
real acquisition by Mr Bretten of the RDSs. As “paid” in paragraph 2(2)(b)
refers to what was really paid, then “acquisition” in the same sub-clause refers
a real acquisition where the acquirer takes on real choice in how to dispose of
the asset and the risk of change in value that goes with ownership of assets.
148. So I agree with
HMRC that the true acquirer of the RDS was Trust 2 and that, therefore, Mr Bretten,
although he paid £500,000 to become the owner of the RDSs, did not pay an
amount in respect of his acquisition of the securities within the
purposively construed meaning of paragraph 2(2)(b). His appeal fails on this
ground too.
HMRC’s third argument
149. I will consider
HMRC’s third argument too, for the sake of completeness, although I recognise
it is not necessary for my decision. This is the claim that paragraph 9A
applies if the transactions are looked at realistically.
150. Paragraph 9A is
an anti-avoidance provision which I have set out above at paragraph 55. There
are a number of pre-conditions to its operation:
(a)
The RDS must be issued to the taxpayer;
(b)
The taxpayer must be connected to the issuer;
(c)
The taxpayer must transfer it to a connected person;
(d)
The amount paid for the RDS on issue must exceed its market value at
that time.
151. This provision
would have caught the planning schemes in cases such as Campbell, Audley and
Pike had it been in force at the time. Read literally, it does
not catch the planning in this case as Mr Bretten was not connected to OCL
which issued the RDS. Mr Bretten also says that the issue price of the RDS was
not at an overvalue.
152. HMRC’s case is
that viewed realistically Trust 1 was the issuer and it is not in dispute that
Mr Bretten was connected with Trust 1. They say Trust 1 should be viewed as
the issuer because Trust 1 was always intended to be substituted for OCL as
debtor on the loan notes. OCL’s role was always intended to be fleeting and
without risk and OCL was only inserted into the transaction for tax avoidance
purposes and in particular to ensure the issue was by a company.
153. I agree with
HMRC that Paragraph 9A should be interpreted purposively. Paragraph 9A was an
anti- tax avoidance provision which had the purpose of preventing persons
artificially generating a loss for tax purposes. It cannot have been intended
by Parliament that it would be interpreted mechanistically or overly literally.
154. Mr Bretten’s
position is that “issuer” cannot have been intended to mean any one other than
the actual issuer and that to try to attribute any broader meaning to the
language is to strain it beyond what it can bear. I am unable to agree with
this.
155. As Paragraph 9A
was clearly aimed at situations where a person would pay more for an asset than
it was actually worth in order to generate an artificial loss for tax
purposes. It is obvious, and the section contemplates, that a person would
only be wiling to do this in a transaction with a connected party. Parliament
must have intended “issuer” in Paragraph 9A(1)(b) to refer to the person who
was, in reality, looking at the overall composite transaction, the issuer, and
that the real issuer would be the person who was intended to receive the
benefit of the fall in value of the RDS.
156. Looking at the
reality of the planned transactions, Trust 1 was always intended to be
substituted for OCL. And further, it was always intended that the loss – the
devaluation of the RDS - would only arise once Trust 1 had been substituted.
The only occasion on when there was any chance that Trust 1 would not be
substituted, was if Mr Bretten chose to collapse the scheme early by exercising
the right to redemption. And as I have said before this should be discounted
as (a) there was only a remote likelihood of it occurring, (b) opt outs should
be irrelevant when considering whether there was a composite transaction and
(c) it acted like an opt out so that if account is taken of it,
realistically the scheme should only be seen as commencing at the time at when
it was clear the opt out would not be exercised, which was after Trust 1
had been substituted as debtor on the loan notes. So either way, realistically
speaking, Trust 1 was the issuer of the loan notes.
157. There was never
any intention whatsoever that OCL would own the RDSs at the time their market
value decreased from approximately face value to 5%. Contrary to
self-interest, if Mr Bretten had intended OCL to benefit from the fall in
value, then I think OCL would have to be seen as the issuer for the purposes of
Paragraph 9A. But this was not the case. Trust 1 was intended to be the
debtor on the RDSs at the time of their decrease in value: and it was the
person intended to be the debtor at the time of the devaluation that Parliament
intended to be within the meaning of issuer. So Trust 1 was the issuer.
158. And Mr Bretten
was connected with Trust 1. He was settlor, a trustee and a beneficiary of
it. His connection with Trust 1 was not in dispute, but for completeness this
can be seen from paragraph 9A(5) which incorporates the definition of
“connected” from s 839 Taxes Act 1988. And that section provides that at (3)
that a trustee is connected with the settlor. In this case one of the trustees
is the settlor, and the other trustee is connected with the settlor.
159. But for
Paragraph 9A to bite, HMRC have to go further and show that the loan notes were
issued at a value exceeding their market value at that time. Mr Bretten
accepted at the hearing, as mentioned above in paragraph 20, and relying on the
definition of market value explained in paragraph 53, that the market value at
time of issue was a little less than the issue price.
160. However the
difference in market value and face value at the date of issue would not be
very great because the securities were, it is accepted, issued at full value,
and it is just that the hypothetical willing purchaser would expect a small
discount to reflect its trouble and expense in being involved in the purchase
and then immediate redemption of the loan notes, that means its market value is
a little lower.
161. HMRC’s case is
that this slight undervalue is enough to capture Mr Bretten’s transaction
because he should be regarded as connected with the issuer. But if HMRC were
right on this, it would mean that even RDS issued at arms length in
transactions which were not part of a pre-ordained tax avoidance scheme, would
also not be issued at arms length. I agree with Mr Bretten that viewed realistically,
Parliament cannot have intended paragraph 9A(1)(c) to capture a situation where
the RDS was not issued at an undervalue, but because there would be a slight
discount on a hypothetical resale on the open market, the issue price
nevertheless slightly exceeds the market value as defined.
162. However, as I
have said before one cannot view the facts realistically without considering
whether the legislation lends itself to a purposive construction. “Market
value” is a defined term and it seems this must be interpreted mechanistically
because it is a deeming provision. However the word “exceeds” in paragraph
9A(1)(c) is not a deeming provision. Realistically speaking, the amount paid
must exceed market value and in a case where this is only strictly true because
market value is assessed by looking at a hypothetical purchaser rather than
actual issue, it cannot realistically be said issue price exceeds market
value.
163. HMRC’s
alternative case is that I should take the market value as at day 15, after the
RDS fell to its real value rather than the artificially inflated value of the
first 14 days. They cite the First Tier Tribunal (Judge Brannan and Ms
Redston) decision in Blumental [2012] UKFTT 497 (TC), which was a case
involving a tax avoidance scheme around qualifying corporate bonds, where the
Tribunal said:
“Construing sections 116(10) and 272 TCGA
purposively, the references in those provisions to “market value” and the
“price which those assets might reasonably be expected to fetch on he sale in
the open market” do not refer to a value or price which has been artificially
manipulated, solely for tax purposes, in a wholly un-commercial fashion to
produce a temporarily depressed value. There was no commercial or economic
reason why the value of the Loan Notes should have been reduced to [figure].
The value thus manipulated is not the value or the price which the relevant
statutory provisions, construed purposively envisage.”
164. I have sympathy
with HMRC’s view that s 272 TCGA was intended to provide an open market
valuation and so (looking at a pre-determined series of transactions) where the
value of an asset is artificially inflated or depressed as part of that
pre-determined series of transactions, the market value was intended by
Parliament to be measured before or after the artificial manipulation.
However, I don’t think I need to determine this because I think HMRC’s third
case fails for another reason.
165. This is that
where paragraph 9A(1)(c) refers to “the amount paid by the relevant person in
respect of his acquisition of the security…”, this must have been intended to
have exactly the same meaning as “the amount paid by that person in respect of
his acquisition of the security..” in paragraph 2(2)(b) as it is in the same
Schedule and refers to the same event.
166. However, in
respect of HMRC’s second argument, I have already said that the amount “paid”
in Paragraph 2(2)(b) was £25,000. £25,000 clearly does not exceed £500,000 or
the market value of the RDS on the date of issue or even the market value at
day 15 (which was £25,000). Therefore the amount paid in Paragraph 9A(1)(c)
does not exceed the market value of the security.
167. And this cannot
be a surprising conclusion. Paragraph 9A is an anti-avoidance provision
predicated on the basis that a scheme of the sort in Audley actually
worked if the legislation were left unamended. But Astell and Audley
show that on a proper interpretation of paragraph 2, these schemes don’t
work. Paragraph 9A is superfluous. It can’t bite. The sort of scheme it was
intended to bite on doesn’t even get as far as paragraph 9A because the amount
“paid” was what was really paid and that (in an avoidance case) will not exceed
its actual value.
168. In conclusion,
HMRC succeed in their first and second but not their third arguments. In any
event, the appeal is dismissed.
169. This document
contains full findings of fact and reasons for the decision. Any party
dissatisfied with this decision has a right to apply for permission to appeal
against it pursuant to Rule 39 of the Tribunal Procedure (First-tier Tribunal)
(Tax Chamber) Rules 2009. The application must be received by this Tribunal
not later than 56 days after this decision is sent to that party. The parties
are referred to “Guidance to accompany a Decision from the First-tier Tribunal
(Tax Chamber)” which accompanies and forms part of this decision notice.
BARBARA
MOSEDALE
TRIBUNAL JUDGE
RELEASE DATE: 14 March 2013