BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £1, it will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
United Kingdom Competition Appeals Tribunal |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> United Kingdom Competition Appeals Tribunal >> Napp Pharmaceutical Holdings Ltd & Ors v Office of Communications [2002] CAT 1 (15 January 2002) URL: http://www.bailii.org/uk/cases/CAT/2002/1.html Cite as: [2002] CAT 1, [2002] Comp AR 13, [2002] ECC 13, (2002) 64 BMLR 165 |
[New search] [Help]
|
||||
IN THE COMPETITION
COMMISSION |
||||
|
||||
APPEAL TRIBUNAL |
Case No. 1001/1/1/01 |
|||
|
||||
New Court Carey Street London
WC2A 2JT |
15 January 2002 |
|||
|
||||
Before:
SIR CHRISTOPHER
BELLAMY
(President)
MR BARRY COLGATE
PROFESSOR PETER
GRINYER |
||||
|
||||
BETWEEN: |
||||
|
||||
NAPP PHARMACEUTICAL HOLDINGS LIMITED AND
SUBSIDIARIES |
||||
|
||||
Applicant |
||||
|
||||
and |
||||
|
||||
DIRECTOR GENERAL OF FAIR TRADING |
||||
|
||||
Respondent |
||||
|
||||
Mr Nicholas Green QC (instructed by Messrs Herbert Smith)
appeared for the Applicant
Mr Peter Roth QC and Mr Jon
Turner (instructed by The Director of Legal Services, Office of Fair
Trading) appeared for the Respondent |
||||
|
||||
JUDGMENT (Non-confidential
version): |
||||
|
||||
Note: Excisions in this
judgment relate to commercially confidential information: Section 56 and
Schedule 8, paragraph 4(3) of the Competition Act
1998. |
||||
|
||||
|
||
2 |
||
|
||
|
||
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Paragraph
I
INTRODUCTION
..........................................................................................1..
The statutory framework
...................................................................................2..
General background
........................................................................................11..
II
THE DECISION AND DIRECTIONS
The Administrative procedure
........................................................................23..
The Director’s findings on
dominance ...........................................................27..
The Director’s findings on abuse
....................................................................32..
Discounts to hospitals
.............................................................................33..
Excessive prices
......................................................................................56..
The Penalty
.....................................................................................................70..
The Directions
.................................................................................................71..
III
THE PROCEDURE BEFORE THE TRIBUNAL
.....................................72..
IV
THE BURDEN AND STANDARD OF PROOF
........................................91..
V
OTHER PROCEDURAL ISSUES
............................................................114..
VI
DOMINANCE
Relevant market
............................................................................................148..
Dominant position
.........................................................................................153..
VII
ABUSE: DISCOUNTS TO HOSPITALS
.................................................170..
A: ARGUMENTS OF THE
PARTIES
Napp’s arguments
.........................................................................................171..
The Director’s arguments
.............................................................................199..
B: THE RELEVANT LAW
.........................................................................207..
C: FINDINGS
Preliminary analysis
......................................................................................217..
Napp’s “net revenue” defence
......................................................................231..
Clarification of terms
............................................................................232..
i |
||
|
||
|
||
Paragraph
The follow-on effect as alleged
by Napp ..............................................239..
Conceptual problems with Napp’s
net revenue test ..............................258..
The effect of Napp’s hospital
pricing policy on competition ...............267..
Asymmetry: Napp’s advantages over
its competitors ..........................289..
The market since 1 March 2000
...........................................................301..
Intention to eliminate
competition ........................................................307..
Conclusion on Napp’s net revenue
defence ..................................................334..
Napp’s other arguments
................................................................................340..
Conclusion
....................................................................................................352..
VIII
ABUSE: EXCESSIVE PRICES
A: ARGUMENTS OF THE PARTIES
........................................................353..
B: LAW
........................................................................................................386..
C: FINDINGS
..............................................................................................389..
The abuse as found in the
Decision ..............................................................390..
Napp’s defence based on the PPRS
..............................................................406..
The Director’s alleged “change of
case” .......................................................428..
Conclusion
....................................................................................................442..
IX
THE PENALTY
A: INTENTIONALLY OR NEGLIGENTLY
.............................................443..
Arguments of the parties
.......................................................................443..
Law
.......................................................................................................452..
Findings on intentionally or
negligently ...............................................459..
B: THE AMOUNT OF THE PENALTY
....................................................473..
The Director’s Guidance
.......................................................................473..
The Director’s approach in the
Decision ..............................................481..
Arguments of the parties
.......................................................................487..
Findings
................................................................................................497..
General observations
....................................................................497..
ii |
||
|
||
|
||
Paragraph
The issue of duration in relation
to hospital pricing .....................504..
The gain at Step 3
.........................................................................507..
Aggravation at Step 4
...................................................................512..
Factors affecting the amount of
the penalty in the present case ...517..
The Tribunal’s assessment of the
penalty .....................................535..
Interest on the penalty
...................................................................542..
X
THE DIRECTIONS
The letter of 4 May 2001
..............................................................................544..
Arguments of the parties
...............................................................................548..
Findings
........................................................................................................553..
XI
ORDERS MADE
.........................................................................................563.. |
||
|
||
Note: For simplicity, this
judgment will refer throughout to Articles 81 and 82 of the EC Treaty,
whether in citations from judgments or otherwise, notwithstanding that the
original citation referred to Articles 85 and 86 of the EC Treaty which
were renumbered as Articles 81 and 82 by the Treaty of Amsterdam with
effect from 1 May 1999. |
||
|
||
iii |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
I – INTRODUCTION
(i) the decision by the Director
General of Fair Trading (“the Director”) dated 30 March 2001 (“the
Decision”) which found that Napp had abused a dominant position in the
supply of sustained release morphine tablets and capsules in the United
Kingdom, contrary to the Chapter II prohibition of the Competition Act
1998, and imposed a penalty of £3.21 million; and
(ii) the directions made by the
Director dated 4 May 2001 (“the Directions”) regulating the prices at
which Napp’s sustained release morphine products are to be
sold.
Earlier decisions of this
Tribunal on 22 May, 10 July and 8 August 2001 have previously dealt with
interim relief and various interlocutory matters: see [2001] CompAR 1, 21
and 33.
The statutory framework
“18.–(1) … [A]ny conduct on the
part of one or more undertakings which amounts to the abuse of a dominant
position in a market is prohibited if it may affect trade within the
United Kingdom.
(2) Conduct may, in particular, constitute such an abuse
if it consists in–
(a) directly or
indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair
trading conditions;
(b) limiting
production, markets or technical development to the prejudice of
consumers;
(c) applying
dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading
parties, thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage;
(d) making the
conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by the other parties of
supplementary obligations which, by their nature or according to
commercial usage, have no connection with the subject of the
contracts.
(3) In this
section–
“dominant position” means a
dominant position within the United Kingdom; and “the United Kingdom”
means the United Kingdom or any part of it.
(4) The prohibition imposed
by subsection (1) is referred to in this Act as “the Chapter II
prohibition”.” |
||
|
||
1 |
||
|
||
|
||
9. The
powers of this Tribunal to determine appeals under section 46 are set out
in paragraph 3 of Schedule 8 of the Act, which provides:
“3.–(1) The tribunal must
determine the appeal on the merits by reference to the grounds of appeal
set out in the notice of appeal.
2 |
||
|
||
|
||
(2) The tribunal may confirm
or set aside the decision which is the subject of the appeal, or any part
of it, and may–
(a) remit the matter to the
Director,
(b) impose or revoke, or vary the amount of, a
penalty,
(c) grant or cancel
an individual exemption or vary any conditions or obligations imposed in
relation to the exemption by the Director,
(d) give such
directions, or take such other steps, as the Director could himself have
given or taken, or
(e) make any other decision which the Director
could himself have made.
(3) Any decision of the
tribunal on an appeal has the same effect, and may be enforced in the same
manner, as a decision of the Director.
(4) If the tribunal confirms the
decision which is the subject of the appeal it may nevertheless set aside
any finding of fact on which the decision was based.”
General Background
3 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
4 |
||
|
||
|
||
II – THE DECISION AND
DIRECTIONS The Administrative procedure
5 |
||
|
||
|
||
Napp under section 26 of the Act,
required notably the production of minutes of meetings of directors of
members of the Napp group and all documents prepared for those meetings
relating to the pricing of MST tablets for the period from 1 January 1997,
as well as a great deal of other specified documents and
information.
The Director’s findings on
dominance
6 |
||
|
||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Table 2: Napp’s market share (unit volumes) of sustained
release morphine tablets/capsules 1997-2000 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Table 3: Shares of supply
(unit volumes) of sustained release morphine tablets/capsules to the
community 1997-2000 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Table 4: Shares of supply (unit volumes) of sustained
release morphine tablets/capsules to hospitals
1997-2000 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
7 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||
(i) regulatory barriers to entry,
that is to say the need for any new competitor to obtain the necessary
manufacturing, marketing or import authorisations required under the
Medicines Act 1968 and other legislation governing medicinal products
(paragraphs 102 and 103);
(ii) what the Director describes
as Napp’s “strong and persistent first mover advantage” (paragraphs 104 to
113); and
(iii) what the Director describes
as “the strategic barrier to entry in hospital sales” created by the
pricing behaviour of Napp in the hospital segment of the market
(paragraphs 114 to 118).
The Director’s findings on abuse
“(a) while charging high prices
to customers in the community segment of the market, supplied sustained
release morphine tablets and capsules to hospitals at discounts which have
the object and effect of hindering competition in the market for the
supply of sustained release morphine tablets and capsules in the UK. The
pricing behaviour of Napp has to be considered as a whole, but the
particular aspects in |
||
|
||
8 |
||
|
||
|
||
which, in the circumstances of
the present case, its discounting behaviour is abusive under section 18 of
the Act are as follows:
(i) selectively supplying
sustained release morphine tablets and capsules to customers in the
hospital segment at lower prices than to customers in the community
segment;
(ii) more particularly, targeting
competitors, both by supplying at higher discounts to hospitals where it
faced (or anticipated) competition and by supplying at higher discounts on
those strengths of sustained release morphine tablets and capsules where
it faced competition; and
(iii) supplying sustained release
morphine tablets and capsules to hospitals at excessively low
prices.
Moreover Napp has engaged in the
above conduct with the intention of eliminating competition.
(b) charged excessive prices to
customers in the community segment of the market for the supply of
sustained release morphine tablets and capsules in the UK.
In doing so, Napp has abused its
dominant position in the market for the supply of sustained release
morphine tablets and capsules in the UK.”
Discounts to hospitals
|
||
|
||
9 |
||
|
||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Table 5: Napp’s average variable cost on MST tablets and
average hospital prices, March to May 2000 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
10 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||
40. In those
circumstances the Director considers that Napp has abused its dominant
position from 1 March 2000 by seeking to eliminate competition in the
hospital sector by pricing below direct costs and selectively targeting
competitors: see notably Case C-62/86 AKZO Chemie BV v Commission
[1991] ECR I-3359 (“AKZO”) (paragraphs 188 to
196).
“[the] lack of sales was
primarily due to predatory pricing in the hospital sector of the market
and in 1999 we have had to adjust our sales strategy to compete on price.
As a result we are now in a position of having to almost give away product
to compete with Napp in the hospital market. Of course we are losing money
and as a small company I |
||
|
||
11 |
||
|
||
|
||
am not sure that we can continue
this policy, reluctant as I am to be ‘bullied’ out of the market by our
much larger competitor.” (paragraph 116)
(i) Napp’s sales to hospitals at
discounted prices, although apparently below direct cost, were
incrementally profitable because of the compensating margins to be earned
on the “follow-on” sales in the community segment (paragraphs 148, 149 and
192).
(ii) What was true for Napp was
true for its competitors, who could equally earn compensating margins in
the community sector (paragraph 148).
(iii) The market was not foreclosed (paragraphs 167 to
169).
(iv) Napp’s discounts to
hospitals were the inevitable result of the necessity to meet competition
(paragraph 197).
|
||
|
||
12 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
13 |
||
|
||
|
||
Excessive prices
“if it is above that which would
exist in a competitive market and where it is clear that high profits will
not stimulate successful new entry within a reasonable period. Therefore,
to show that prices are excessive, it must be demonstrated that (i) prices
are higher than would be expected in a competitive market, and (ii) there
is no effective competitive pressure to bring them down to competitive
levels, nor is there likely to be.”
57. According
to the Director, Napp’s prices can be shown to be above the competitive
level, first, by assessing “whether the difference between costs actually
incurred and the price actually charged is excessive”: Case 27/76
United Brands v Commission [1978] ECR 207 (“United Brands”).
In the Decision, the Director has sought to do this by showing the profit
margins Napp earns on community sales and comparing these with the margins
Napp earns on sales of other products, and on sales of MST to other
markets (paragraph 204).
|
||
|
||
14 |
||
|
||
|
||
excessive (paragraph 206). Napp
does not dispute the Director’s figures, but does not accept his
conclusion.
— Comparisons of
the prices for MST tablets with those of Napp’s competitors (paragraphs
207 to 212)
— Comparison of prices for MST tablets over time
(paragraphs 213 to 216)
— Comparison of
the prices of MST charged to hospitals and the community respectively
(paragraphs 217 to 220)
|
||
|
||
15 |
||
|
||
|
||
— Comparison with Napp’s export prices (paragraphs
218, 219, 221 and 222)
— Comparisons of
Napp’s profitability on sales to hospitals and the community (paragraphs
223 to 226)
— Comparison of Napp’s margins with those of its
competitors (paragraphs 226 to 229)
16 |
||
|
||
|
||
manufactures MST tablets, while
its competitors contract out the manufacture, and the possibility that
Napp’s operations may be more efficient, the Director has calculated
Napp’s gross profit margin, using the average costs of its next most
profitable competitor, in order to ensure that any comparison is made on
the basis most favourable to Napp. Even when calculated on this basis,
according to the Director, Napp’s prices imply margins of 80.5 per cent
compared to [...] [less than 70] per cent for the next most profitable
competitor. This further supports the conclusion that Napp’s prices to the
community are excessive and not subject to normal competitive constraints
(paragraphs 228 and 229).
The penalty
The Directions
|
||
|
||
17 |
||
|
||
|
||
III – PROCEDURE BEFORE THE TRIBUNAL
73. Napp’s
notice of appeal was lodged with the Registry on 29 May 2001 accompanied
by a number of witness statements and over 4000 pages of supporting
documents and correspondence exchanged with the Director during the
administrative procedure. Notice of the appeal was published in the
London, Edinburgh and Belfast Gazettes on 1 June 2001 and also on the
Tribunal’s website (www.competition-commission.org.uk)
pursuant to Rule 13(1) of the Tribunal’s Rules. No requests to intervene
in the proceedings were received.
|
||
|
||
18 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
19 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
20 |
||
|
||
|
||
87. Following the hearing,
further written submissions were made, at the Tribunal’s request,
principally as regards (i) the relevance or admissibility of the documents
disclosed pursuant to the Tribunal’s request of 31 August 2001; and (ii)
whether Napp’s prices fell below direct costs in 1998 or earlier (see the letters of the
parties of 5, 15, 17 and 22 October 2001).
88. We comment, for the
benefit of those conducting future appeals, that the procedure in this
case did not go entirely according to the plan envisaged in the Tribunal’s
Guide to Appeals under the Competition Act, probably for three
reasons: the notice of appeal was not as focussed as we would have wished, the Director sought to
introduce a good deal of material and argument that was not in
the Decision, and some of the
supplementary materials supplied by Napp on such matters as the Human
Rights Act and PCGs/PCTs were not in a form which we could easily absorb.
We entirely appreciate the difficulties of the subject matter, the
pressure of time, and the fact that all concerned are on a learning curve
as regards the procedures to be followed in appeals under the Act, but we
hope that the principles of the Guide can be closely followed in
future cases.
89. Napp requests the Tribunal
to:
- set aside
the Decision in whole or in part;
- set aside or
vary the Directions;
- to set
aside or reduce the penalty;
- declare that
Napp’s conduct does not infringe the Chapter II prohibition;
- order the
Director to pay Napp’s costs of and incidental to the appeal;
- order such
further or other relief as the Tribunal may consider
appropriate.
90. The Director requests the Tribunal
to:
- dismiss
Napp’s appeal;
- order Napp
to pay his costs;
- order,
pursuant to Rule 27 of the Tribunal’s Rules, that interest be payable on
the penalty.
IV - THE BURDEN AND STANDARD OF PROOF
91. This is the first appeal
under the Act against an infringement decision, so we address at the
outset the issue of the burden and standard of proof where penalties are
imposed under section 36 of the Act.
21 |
||
|
||
|
||
“Right to a Fair Trial
1. In the
determination of his civil rights and obligations or of any criminal
charge against him, everyone is entitled to a fair and public hearing
within a reasonable time by an independent and impartial tribunal
established by law. Judgment shall be pronounced publicly ...
2. Everyone charged
with a criminal offence shall be presumed innocent until proved guilty
according to law.
3. Everyone charged
with a criminal office has the following minimum rights:
(a) to be informed
promptly, in a language which he understands and in detail, of the nature
and cause of the accusation against him;
(b) to have adequate
time and facilities for the preparation of his defence;
(c) to defend
himself in person or through legal assistance of his own choosing or, if
he has not sufficient means to pay for legal assistance, to be given it
free when the interests of justice so require;
(d) to examine or
have examined witnesses against him and to obtain the attendance and
examination of witnesses on his behalf under the same conditions as
witnesses against him;
...”
|
||
|
||
|
||
95. The Director argues that the
fact that the present proceedings involve a criminal charge for the
purpose of the ECHR does not mean that they are to be equated with
criminal proceedings under English law, or that the rights that apply in
criminal proceedings automatically apply to a case under the Act: see the
decision of the Court of Appeal in Han v Commissioners of Customs and
Excise, [2001] 4 All ER 687. As regards the burden of proof, the
Director accepts that it is incumbent upon him to establish the
infringement, and that the persuasive burden of proof
remains |
||
|
||
22 |
||
|
||
|
||
attendance and examination of
witnesses on his behalf under the same conditions as witnesses against
him” (Article 6(3)(d)).
|
||
|
||
24 |
||
|
||
|
||
we must apply in deciding whether
infringements of the Chapter I or Chapter II prohibitions are proved is
the civil standard, commonly known as the preponderance or balance of
probabilities, notwithstanding that the civil penalties imposed may be
intended by the Director to have a deterrent effect.
25 |
||
|
||
|
||
financial penalties. It is for
the Director to satisfy us in each case, on the basis of strong and
compelling evidence, taking account of the seriousness of what is alleged,
that the infringement is duly proved, the undertaking being entitled to
the presumption of innocence, and to any reasonable doubt there may
be.
110. That approach
does not in our view preclude the Director, in discharging the burden of
proof, from relying, in certain circumstances, from inferences or
presumptions that would, in the absence of any countervailing indications,
normally flow from a given set of facts, for example that dominance may be
inferred from very high market shares (Case 85/76 Hoffman-La Roche v
Commission [1979] ECR 461, paragraph 41); that sales below average
variable costs may, in the absence of rebuttal, be presumed to be
predatory (see the opinion of Advocate General Fennelly in Cases C-395/96P
and 396/96P Compagnie Maritime Belge v Commission [2000] ECR I-1442
at paragraph 127); or that an undertaking’s presence at a meeting with a
manifestly anti-competitive purpose implies, in the absence of
explanation, participation in the cartel alleged: Montecatini v
Commission, cited above, at paragraphs 177 to 181.
|
||
|
||
26 |
||
|
||
|
||
suffisance de droit), but there
is no doubt that, in general, those Courts require convincing proof that
the alleged infringements have been committed in the form of a “firm,
precise and consistent body of evidence”: see Cases 29 and 30/83 CRAM
and Rheinzink v Commission cited above, paragraphs 16 to 20; Cases
C-89/85 etc Ahlström Osakeyhtiö and others v Commission [1993] ECR I-1307, paragraph 127. We have no reason to suppose that the standard of
proof we propose to follow is any different from that followed in practice
by the courts in Luxembourg.
V – OTHER PROCEDURAL ISSUES
The Director’s witness statements
27 |
||
|
||
|
||
“It is our intention that the
tribunal should be primarily concerned with the correctness or otherwise
of the conclusions contained in the appealed decision and not with how the
decision was reached or the reasoning expressed in it. That will apply
unless defects in how the decision was reached or the reasoning make it
impracticable for the tribunal fairly to determine the correctness or
otherwise of the conclusions or of any directions contained in the
decision. Wherever possible, we want the tribunal to decide a case on the
facts before it, even where there has been a procedural error, and to
avoid remitting the case to the director general. We intend to reflect
that policy in the tribunal rules.
This is an important aspect of
our policy, and I shall explain the rationale behind our approach. The
Bill provides for a full appeal on the merits of the case, which is an
essential part of ensuring the fairness and transparency of the new
regime. It enables undertakings to appeal the substance of the decision
including in those cases where it is believed that a failure on the part
of the director general to follow proper procedures has led him to reach
an incorrect conclusion. The fact that the tribunal will be reconsidering
the decision on the merits will enable it to remedy the consequences of
any defects in the director general’s procedures.”
|
||
|
||
28 |
||
|
||
|
||
Napp’s principal submission that
nothing may be relied on before the Tribunal unless it was relied on in
the administrative procedure.
|
||
|
||
29 |
||
|
||
|
||
the follow-on effect alleged by
Napp. Although largely relating to events before the alleged period of
infringement, Napp relies strongly on Mr Penrose’s evidence on at least
one point, namely that it was BIL rather than Napp which initiated price
cutting after 1994. We see no proper basis for excluding Mr Penrose’s
evidence, although it is not essential to our analysis of Napp’s conduct
during the period of infringement.
The documents disclosed following the Tribunal’s request of
31 August 2001
30 |
||
|
||
|
||
as we could see without referring
to any documents tending to show what matters Napp had actually taken into
account at the material time. We therefore asked for documents relating to
the objectives, strategy or policy considerations taken into account by
Napp in setting its prices in the periods referred to in the Decision to
be drawn to our attention. The documents concerned were promptly supplied
without objection on Napp’s part.
The “Ermakov” issue
132. Napp now argues
on the basis of R v Westminster City Council ex parte Ermakov
[1996] 2 All ER 302 (CA), followed for example in Nash v Chelsea
Royal College of Art (Burnton J, [2001] EWHC Admin 538), that the
Director should not be permitted to change the reasons for his Decision
before the Tribunal, nor add supplementary reasons, given in particular
that the Director is a specialist decision maker. In Ermakov, the
Court of Appeal decided that, in certain proceedings under the Housing Act
1996, the decision maker should be held to the reasons given in his
original decision, in the interests of fairness and efficient decision
making: see Hutchison LJ at pp. 315 to 317.
|
||
|
||
31 |
||
|
||
|
||
the safeguards it provides,
largely devoid of purpose; the function of this Tribunal is not to try a
wholly new case. If the Director wishes to make a new case, the proper
course is for the Director to withdraw the decision and adopt a new
decision, or for this Tribunal to remit.
Human Rights and general issues of
unfairness
|
||
|
||
32 |
||
|
||
|
||
commercial confidentiality had
been claimed by third parties pursuant to Rule 14(6)(a) and Rule 30(1)(c)
of the Director’s Rules. A Schedule listing all the documents in the
Director’s possession, identifying those which had not been disclosed in
whole or part, was supplied to Napp. Upon the lodging of the appeal, the
Director disclosed further documents to named external advisers of Napp,
who gave undertakings to observe the confidentiality of the documents in
question. Material relating to the discounting of products other than oral
sustained release morphine was disclosed by the Director in the defence.
The witness statements of Mr Hartley and Mr Penrose before the Tribunal
contained a great deal of further material about the commercial strategies
pursued in relation to Zomorph and Oramorph, respectively.
|
||
|
||
34 |
||
|
||
|
||
VI – DOMINANCE Relevant
market
|
||
|
||
35 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
36 |
||
|
||
|
||
Dominant position
“relates to a position of
economic strength enjoyed by an undertaking which enables it to prevent
effective competition being maintained on the relevant market by affording
it the power to behave to an appreciable extent independently of its
competitors, its customers and ultimately of consumers.”
Case 85/76 Hoffman-La Roche v Commission [1979] ECR 461, paragraph 38.
“The existence of a dominant
position may derive from several factors which, taken separately, are not
necessarily determinative but among these factors a highly important one
is the existence of very large market shares.”
And at paragraph 41:
“Furthermore although the
importance of the market shares may vary from one market to another the
view may legitimately be taken that very large shares are in themselves,
and save in exceptional circumstances, evidence of the existence of a
dominant position.” |
||
|
||
37 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
38 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
39 |
||
|
||
|
||
portfolio based approach of the
PPRS is to be preferred, when it comes to determining whether the price of
MST is excessive for the purposes of the Chapter II prohibition. But those
arguments which in any event we reject at paragraphs 406 et seq below, go
to the question of abuse, and not to the prior question of the
existence of a dominant position.
“If anti-competitive conduct is
required of undertakings by national legislation or if the latter creates
a legal framework which itself eliminates any possibility of competitive
activity on their part, Articles 81 and 82 do not apply. In such a
situation, the restriction of competition is not attributable, as those
provisions implicitly require, to the autonomous conduct of the
undertakings ... Articles 81 and 82 may apply, however, if it is found
that the national legislation does not preclude undertakings from engaging
in autonomous conduct which prevents, restricts or distorts competition
...”
(paragraph 130).
VII – ABUSE: DISCOUNTS TO HOSPITALS
|
||
|
||
40 |
||
|
||
|
||
hospital segment of the market is
the only viable point of entry into the market as a whole. Hence the
alleged abuse in the hospital segment, while a discrete abuse and
significant in its own right, is also, says the Director, a means to an
end, namely the preservation of Napp’s prices and market share in the much
larger community segment of the market. Although we analyse the two abuses
separately, the connection between the hospital and community segments
must be borne in mind throughout this judgment.
A. ARGUMENTS OF THE PARTIES
Napp’s arguments
|
||
|
||
41 |
||
|
||
|
||
hospital price plus the sale of
“follow on” units to the community segment at the community price) is
profitable. Such transactions cover not only Napp’s average variable
costs, but also Napp’s average total cost: see Table 2.2 of document A107.
Even assuming that one unit of hospital sales led to the sale of only 0.25
follow-on units in the community, Napp would still be covering its average
total costs: see Table 2.3 of document A107. Even at the reduced NHS
prices required by the Directions, the hospital prices currently charged
for MST would be profitable for Napp (i.e. cover average total costs),
once the follow-on sales are taken into account, so long as one unit sold
in a hospital generated at least 0.30 units of follow-on sales in the
community sector: Table 2.4 of document A107. It would require a linkage
of only 0.04 follow-on units for Napp to cover its direct
costs.
“Napp considers that it makes
sense to discount MST substantially to win hospital contracts, to take
account of the fact that there is some linkage, albeit one that it is
difficult to quantify, between sales in hospitals and sales in the
community. Given that, under the PPRS, Napp can charge prices for its
community sales which generate a profit margin of some [...] [in excess of
80]%, Napp does not need to stimulate many sales in the community to
justify a substantial discount of its prices to the hospital sector. Thus
Napp can afford to discount its prices to hospitals substantially, even on
the basis of a fairly modest assumed linkage between hospitals and
community sales, and the hospital sales will still be
profitable.
In short, we did not believe
that, by discounting our prices to the extent that we did to win hospital
contracts, we would be making losses; instead we believed that, if we were
successful in winning contracts, we would thereby make extra sales,
because we could expect to sell extra units of MST in the community
segment, by virtue of the “linkage” referred to in paragraph (ii) above.
We assumed that all bidders were |
||
|
||
42 |
||
|
||
|
||
evaluating the opportunities in
the same way, and were willing to offer discounts on the same
basis.”
“Moreover, I have at all material
times believed that Napp’s discounts to hospitals represented a fair and
normal means of competition: Napp was keen to win hospital contracts, in
recognition of the follow on benefits which they bring, in terms of
community sales. I believed that other suppliers would also recognise
those benefits and, indeed, I believed that that was why other firms
(first Farmitalia, then Boehringer Ingelheim and now Link) were offering
such low prices to hospitals.”
|
||
|
||
43 |
||
|
||
|
||
183. That the benefit
of such linked sales is available to Link is confirmed, says Napp, by a
letter to the OFT by Mr Steven Mountain, the managing director of Link
dated 3rd November 2000 (OFT document 255) where he
says:
“Proof of this link [sc. between
hospital and community] can be seen in the sales of Zomorph capsules over
the last year where the ratio of hospital sales volumes to community sales
volumes is 1:4. Link only has a hospital sales team. We do not call or
advertise to GPs at all, and so the only way that there are any sales of
Zomorph capsules into the community is through hospital influence via
referral and the other methods outlined above.
The MST ratio is currently 1:8
and so it can be seen following conversions that a hospital has an
immediate and direct influence over around 50% of community usage. The
ratio for Zomorph capsules sales will rise further over time as hospital
influence filters through to the community…
We do not dispute Napp’s second
point that Napp makes money overall out of loss leading into hospital. For
every 1 pack they sell into hospital we can see that immediately they
would sell 4 into the community, and in the long term 8. …”
|
||
|
||
44 |
||
|
||
|
||
treatment when making prescribing
decisions. These effects, says Napp, were already being felt by January
2000, just as BIL was leaving the market, and have been successfully
exploited by Link, as shown by Mr Mountain’s letter of 3 November 2000 and
the evidence of Mr Hartley. Napp particularly criticises the Director for
failing to take account of Mr Mountain’s letter in the Decision, despite
Napp’s comments on that letter at the second oral hearing during the
administrative procedure. In fact, Link’s sales have grown substantially
since May 2000, another fact not taken into account by the Director. Napp
states, however, “for the avoidance of doubt” that it is not suggested
that the linkage is entirely automatic, in the sense that no further
effort is required on behalf of the supplier. According to its skeleton
argument, what Napp means by ‘automatic’ is that “a supplier need expend
no more effort than one would reasonably expect of a competent supplier”
(paragraph 85).
45 |
||
|
||
|
||
and not in danger of going out of
business. APS Berk, Lanacher and CeNeS are potential new entrants. BIL’s
statements as to why it left the market are self-serving and
dubious.
|
||
|
||
46 |
||
|
||
|
||
not expect Napp to retaliate in
hospitals nor lower their prices in the community. Nor can the Director be
permitted to prove an anti-competitive intent on the basis of the material
disclosed in response to the Tribunal’s request, since that material was
not relied on in the Decision, and predates the period of
infringement.
The Director’s arguments
|
||
|
||
47 |
||
|
||
|
||
market share in the community
segment. Pursuant to AKZO, the burden is on Napp to rebut the
presumption of abuse to which its below-cost sales give rise. According to
the Director, Napp’s arguments based on ‘follow-on effect’ and ‘linkages’
fail to rebut that presumption.
|
||
|
||
48 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
49 |
||
|
||
|
||
B. THE RELEVANT LAW
207. In Case 85/76
Hoffman-La Roche v Commission [1979] ECR 461, which concerned a
system of loyalty rebates operated by the dominant firm which made it
difficult for competitors to enter the market, the Court of Justice stated
at paragraph 91:
“The concept of abuse is an
objective concept relating to the behaviour of an undertaking in a
dominant position which is such as to influence the structure of a market
where, as a result of the very presence of the undertaking in question,
the degree of competition is weakened and which, through recourse to
methods different from those which condition normal competition in
products or services on the basis of the transactions of commercial
operators, has the effect of hindering the maintenance of the degree of
competition still existing in the market or the growth of that
competition.”
“A finding that an undertaking
has a dominant position is not in itself a recrimination but simply means
that, irrespective of the reasons for which it has such a dominant
position, the undertaking concerned has a special responsibility not to
allow its conduct to impair genuine undistorted competition on the common
market.”
209. In AKZO
(Case C-62/86 AKZO Chemie v Commission [1991] ECR I-3359),
where the dominant firm offered prices discounted below cost in order to
force a competitor out of business, the Court held:
“[70] Article 82 prohibits a
dominant undertaking from eliminating a competitor and thereby
strengthening its position by using methods other than those which come
within the scope of competition on the basis of quality. From that point
of view, however, not all competition by means of price can be regarded as
legitimate.
[71] Prices below average
variable costs (that is to say, those which vary depending on the
quantities produced) by means of which a dominant undertaking seeks to
eliminate a competitor must be regarded as abusive. A dominant undertaking
has no interest in applying such prices except that of eliminating
competitors so as to enable it subsequently to raise its prices by taking
advantage of its monopolistic position, since each sale generates a loss,
namely the total amount of the fixed costs (that is to say, those which
remain constant regardless of the quantities produced) and, at least, part
of the variable costs relating to the unit produced.
[72] Moreover, prices below
average total costs, that is to say, fixed costs plus variable costs, but
above average variable costs, must be regarded as abusive if they are
determined as part of a plan for eliminating a competitor. Such prices can
drive from the market undertakings which are perhaps as efficient as the
dominant undertaking but which, because of their smaller financial
resources, are incapable of withstanding the competition waged against
them.” |
||
|
||
50 |
||
|
||
|
||
210. AKZO was
followed in Case T-83/91 Tetra Pak v Commission [1994] ECR II-755),
on appeal, Case 333/94P Tetra Pak v Commission [1996] ECR I-5951
(“Tetra Pak II”). The Court of First Instance, applying the
criteria set out in AKZO, found that certain of Tetra Pak’s prices
were below direct variable costs, and in one case below average variable
cost (paragraph 151), and had no other economic rationale other than
ousting Tetra Pak’s principal competitor (paragraphs 147 to 151, and 188
to 192 of its judgment). On the subsequent appeal the Court of Justice
held at paragraphs 41 to 44:
“41. In AKZO this Court
did indeed sanction the existence of two different methods of analysis for
determining whether an undertaking has practised predatory pricing. First,
prices below average variable costs must always be considered abusive. In
such a case, there is no conceivable economic purpose other than the
elimination of a competitor, since each item produced and sold entails a
loss for the undertaking. Secondly, prices below average total costs but
above average variable costs are only to be considered abusive if an
intention to eliminate can be shown.
42. At paragraph 150 of the
judgment under appeal, the Court of First Instance carried out the same
examination as did this Court in AKZO. For sales of non-aseptic
cartons in Italy between 1976 and 1981, it found that prices were
considerably lower than average variable costs. Proof of intention to
eliminate competitors was therefore not necessary. In 1982, prices for
those cartons lay between average variable costs and average total costs.
For that reason, in paragraph 151 of its judgment, the Court of First
Instance was at pains to establish – and the appellant has not criticised
it in that regard – that Tetra Pak intended to eliminate a competitor.
...
44. Furthermore, it would not be
appropriate, in the circumstances of the present case, to require in
addition proof that Tetra Pak had a realistic chance of recouping its
losses. It must be possible to penalise predatory pricing whenever there
is a risk that competitors will be eliminated. The Court of First Instance
found, at paragraphs 151 and 191 of its judgment, that there was such a
risk in this case. The aim pursued, which is to maintain undistorted
competition, rules out waiting until such a strategy leads to the actual
elimination of competitors.”
|
||
|
||
51 |
||
|
||
|
||
“[146] As has already been
pointed out, it has been consistently held that whilst the fact that an
undertaking is in a dominant position cannot deprive it of entitlement to
protect its own commercial interests if they are attacked; and whilst such
an undertaking must be allowed the right to take such reasonable steps as
it deems appropriate to protect those interests, such behaviour cannot be
allowed if its real purpose is to strengthen this dominant position and
thereby abuse it (in particular, BPB Industries and British Gypsum v
Commission).”
The Court of First Instance held
that the purpose of the practice was to eliminate the conference’s only
competitor, and that, in any event, the response by Cewal to the situation
which it faced was not reasonable and proportionate (paragraphs 147 and
148).
“127. Apparently, therefore,
sales below average variable (or short-run marginal: AKZO,
paragraph 70) costs are in effect presumed to be abusive. While it is
usually rational to sell above average variable costs, because that
permits some return on capital, where the market will not bear a higher
price, it is not usually rational to sell below average variable costs.
Marginal costs need not be incurred and business has no interest in
incurring them so as to make a loss. A dominant firm would be permitted,
however, to rebut this presumption by showing that such pricing was not
part of a plan to eliminate its competitor.”
“132. I would, on the other hand,
accept that, normally, non-discriminatory price cuts by a dominant
undertaking which do not entail below-cost sales should not be regarded as
being anti-competitive. In the first place, even if they are only short
lived, they benefit consumers and, secondly, if the dominant undertaking’s
competitors are equally or more efficient, they should be able to compete
on the same terms. Community competition law should thus not offer less
efficient undertakings a safe haven against vigorous competition even from
dominant undertakings. Different considerations may, however, apply where
an undertaking which enjoys a position of dominance approaching a
monopoly, particularly on a market where price cuts can be implemented
with relative autonomy from costs, implements a policy of selective price
cutting with the demonstrable aim of eliminating all competition. In those
circumstance, to accept that all selling above cost was automatically
acceptable could enable the undertaking in question to eliminate all
competition by pursuing a selective |
||
|
||
52 |
||
|
||
|
||
pricing policy which in the long
run would permit it to increase prices and deter potential future entrants
for fear of receiving the same targeted treatment.”
“137. In all these circumstances,
the Court of First Instance committed no error of law in finding that the
response of Cewal members to the entrance of G&C was not ‘reasonable
and proportionate’. To my mind, Article 86 cannot be interpreted as
permitting monopolists or quasi-monopolists to exploit the very
significant market power which their superdominance confers so as to
preclude the emergence either of a new or additional competitor. Where an
undertaking, or group of undertakings whose conduct must be assessed
collectively, enjoys a position of such overwhelming dominance verging on
monopoly, comparable to that which existed in the present case at the
moment when G&C entered the relevant market, it would not be consonant
with the particularly onerous special obligation affecting such a dominant
undertaking not to impair further the structure of the feeble existing
competition for them to react, even to aggressive price competition from a
new entrant, with a policy of targeted, selective price cuts designed to
eliminate that competitor. Contrary to the assertion of the appellants,
the mere fact that such prices are not pitched at a level that is actually
(or can be shown to be) below total average (or long-run marginal) costs
does not, to my mind, render legitimate the application of such a pricing
policy.”
215. In its judgment in Compagnie Maritime
Belge the Court of Justice held at paragraphs 112 to 120:
“112. It is settled case-law that
the list of abusive practices contained in Article 86 of the Treaty is not
an exhaustive enumeration of the abuses of a dominant position prohibited
by the Treaty (Case 6/72 Europemballage and Continental Can v
Commission [1973] ECR 215, paragraph 26).
113. It is,
moreover, established that, in certain circumstances, abuse may occur if
an undertaking in a dominant position strengthens that position in such a
way that the degree of dominance reached substantially fetters competition
(Europemballage and Continental Can, paragraph 26).
114. Furthermore,
the actual scope of the special responsibility imposed on a dominant
undertaking must be considered in the light of the specific circumstances
of each case which show that competition has been weakened (Case C-333/94
P Tetra Pak v Commission [1996] ECR I-5951, paragraph
24).”
After referring to the specific circumstances of the maritime
transport sector, the Court continued:
“117 It follows that, where a
liner conference in a dominant position selectively cuts its prices in
order deliberately to match those of a competitor, it derives a dual
benefit. First, it eliminates the principal, and possibly the only, means
of competition open to the competing undertaking. Second, it can continue
to require its users to pay higher prices for the services which are not
threatened by that competition.
53 |
||
|
||
|
||
...
119. It is
sufficient to recall that the conduct at issue here is that of a
conference having a share of over 90% of the market in question and only
one competitor. The appellants have, moreover, never seriously disputed,
and indeed admitted at the hearing, that the purpose of the conduct
complained of was to eliminate G&C from the market.
120. The Court of
First Instance did not, therefore, err in law, in holding that the
Commission’s objections to the effect that the practice known as ‘fighting
ships’, as applied against G&C constituted an abuse of a dominant
position were justified. ...”
“it is necessary to consider all
the circumstances, particularly the criteria and rules governing the grant
of the discount, and to investigate whether, in providing an advantage not
based on any economic service justifying it, the discount tends to remove
or restrict the buyer’s freedom to choose his sources of supply, to bar
competitors from access to the market, to apply dissimilar conditions to
equivalent transactions with other trading parties or to strengthen the
dominant position by distorting competition (Hoffman-La Roche,
paragraph 90; Michelin, paragraph 73). The distortion of
competition arises from the fact that the financial advantage granted by
the undertaking in a dominant position is not based on any economic
consideration justifying it, but tends to prevent the customers of that
dominant undertaking from obtaining their supplies from competitors
(Michelin, paragraph 71). One of the circumstances may therefore
consist in the fact that the practice in question takes place in the
context of a plan by the dominant undertaking aimed at eliminating a
competitor (AKZO, paragraph 72; Compagnie Maritime Belge
Transports, paragraphs 147 and 148).”
C. FINDINGS
Preliminary analysis
|
||
|
||
54 |
||
|
||
|
||
view it is relevant to take facts
arising before 1 March 2000 into account for the purpose, but only for the
purpose, of throwing light on facts and matters in issue on and after that
date.
219. In these
circumstances, there is no doubt in our minds that, from 1 March 2000,
Napp had ‘a special responsibility not to allow its conduct to impair
genuine undistorted competition’, as held by the Court of Justice in
Michelin [1983] ECR 3451, at paragraph 57. It is well established
that such a special responsibility may deprive a dominant undertaking of
the right to adopt a course of conduct that would be unobjectionable if
adopted by a non-dominant undertaking (Case T-111/96 ITT Promedia v
Commission [1998] ECR II-2937, paragraph 139), but the actual scope of
that special responsibility must be considered in the light of the
specific circumstances of each case: Compagnie Maritime Belge
[2000] ECR I-1365 at paragraph 114. We for our part accept and follow
the opinion of Mr Advocate General Fennelly in Compagnie Maritime
Belge, cited above, that the special responsibility of a dominant
undertaking is particularly onerous where it is a case of a
quasi-monopolist enjoying “dominance approaching monopoly”,
“superdominance” or “overwhelming dominance verging on monopoly” [2000]
ECR I-1365 at paragraphs 132 and 137. In our view, Napp’s high and
persistent market shares put Napp into the category of “dominance
approaching monopoly” – i.e. superdominance – and the issue of abuse in
this case has to be addressed in that specific context.
|
||
|
||
55 |
||
|
||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Oramorph in 1994, BIL offered
higher discounts to hospitals, which Napp matched. Each time BIL came back
with a higher discount, Napp matched again. As a result, by 1996 Napp’s
discounts to hospitals were some [...] [in excess of 90] per cent if Napp
was the sole supplier. For the purposes of this judgment we are prepared
to assume that the policy of offering higher discounts to hospitals was
originally initiated by BIL. Similarly, it is unnecessary for us to make
any finding on whether there were occasions on which Napp undercut BIL.
For the purposes of this judgment, it is sufficient to find that Napp
pursued a policy of matching BIL’s prices. |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Average direct costs
Average hospital
price
(£ per pack of 60)
(£ per pack
of 60) |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
56 |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||
statement, at paragraph 191 of
the Decision, that such prices are well below direct costs, by up to [...]
[in between 30 to 50] per cent, and do not even cover raw material
costs.
“[71] Prices below average
variable costs (that is to say, those which vary depending on the
quantities produced) by means of which a dominant undertaking seeks to
eliminate a competitor must be regarded as abusive. A dominant undertaking
has no interest in applying such prices except that of eliminating
competitors so as to enable it subsequently to raise its prices by taking
advantage of its monopolistic position, since each sale generates a loss,
namely the total amount of the fixed costs (that is to say, those which
remain constant regardless of the quantities produced) and, at least, part
of the variable costs relating to the unit produced.”
“Prices below average variable
costs must always be considered abusive. In such a case, there is no
conceivable economic purpose other than the elimination of a competitor,
since each item produced and sold entails a loss for the
undertaking.
...
For sales of non-aseptic cartons
in Italy between 1976 and 1981 ... prices were considerably lower than
average variable costs. Proof of intention to eliminate competitors was
therefore not necessary.”
57 |
||
|
||
|
||
on the foregoing facts alone,
that Napp has abused its dominant position in offering prices below
average variable costs to hospitals contrary to the Chapter II
prohibition, as the Director found in the Decision, without it being
necessary to find that Napp had a specific intention to eliminate
competition. In view of the fact that the AKZO approach was laid
down in a case where the dominant undertaking had only 50 per cent of the
market, it seems to us that it is only in the most exceptional of
circumstances that a similar approach should not be applied in cases of
“superdominance” where the undertaking concerned has around 95 per cent of
the market.
Napp’s “net revenue” defence
|
||
|
||
58 |
||
|
||
|
||
Clarification of terms
— The narrow follow-on effect alleged by
Napp
|
||
|
||
59 |
||
|
||
|
||
linkages’ or simply ‘linkages’ in
a wider sense that in our view approximates more to the broader notion of
‘hospital influence’.
— Hospital influence
|
||
|
||
60 |
||
|
||
|
||
The follow-on effect as alleged by Napp
|
||
|
||
61 |
||
|
||
|
||
in hospital (i.e. there is a
hospital sale), and where there is merely a hospital recommendation (but
not necessarily a hospital sale). In Nera’s report of 16 October 2000
(A19) Nera makes it clear that they are referring to “approximately 14.6
per cent of patients [who] consume a brand of SRM heavily influenced
by the brand chosen originally by the hospital doctor (“follow-on
linkages”) (p.1), by reference to “a branded prescription or referral
letter” (p.4) [emphasis added by the Tribunal].
|
||
|
||
62 |
||
|
||
|
||
“it had not located any documents
which discussed follow on linkages and which suggested that on their face
or from their context that such linkages are or should be taken into
account in setting hospital tender prices.”
Contrary to Napp’s suggestion in
argument, we do not find that the documents enclosed with that letter give
rise to any inference that, in setting its tender prices, Napp took
account of a follow-on effect in the narrow sense alleged by
Napp.
63 |
||
|
||
|
||
showing that such a rationale did
in fact form the basis of the company’s policy at the material time. In
the present case, Napp did not choose to do so, either in answer to the
allegations made by the Director, or in the notice of appeal.
|
||
|
||
64 |
||
|
||
|
||
Conceptual problems with Napp’s net revenue
test
|
||
|
||
65 |
||
|
||
|
||
if those loss-making hospital
sales also have the effect of excluding competitors, the very conduct
which is profitable to Napp on a net revenue basis has at the same time
the effect of eliminating competition. That in turn, protects Napp’s
revenues in the community segment. To then argue that the below-cost
pricing in the hospital segment is justified by the revenues from the
community segment is the equivalent of saying that anti-competitive
behaviour which protects Napp’s virtual monopoly can be justified on the
basis of the profits made from the monopoly which the anti-competitive
behaviour is designed to protect. The argument is circular, as the
Director points out at paragraphs 151 and 195 of the
Decision.
263. The second
conceptual weakness in Napp’s argument is its contention that hospital and
community prices are ‘system prices’. In our view that argument depends on
establishing that what is being sold to the buyer is indeed a ‘system’, as
might, at least theoretically, be the case of the sale of razors and razor
blades, or photocopiers and toner cartridges. However, as Canon KK v
Green Cartridge Co [1997] AC 728 (HL) makes clear, an essential aspect
of the legitimate use of system pricing is that the buyer is in a position
to evaluate the life-time, or system-wide costs, and so make a rational
choice between competing possibilities (see the speech of Lord Hoffmann at
pages 737 to 738). Here, that is not the case. During the period of
infringement in this case, there were two separate groups of buyers, the
hospital authorities, and the GPs respectively, rather than a
single |
||
|
||
66 |
||
|
||
|
||
buyer. Neither group of buyers
was motivated to any significant extent to take account of the cost
implications, for the other group, of his decisions, or had the
information to do so rationally. In this case, it seems to us, what Napp
has done is exploit not the connection, but the disconnection
between purchasing decisions taken by the different component parts of
the NHS, thereby maintaining widely different prices to the different
purchasers concerned. That, in our view, is the exact opposite of “system
pricing” as it is properly understood.
|
||
|
||
67 |
||
|
||
|
||
hospital pricing policy on
competition, the alleged ‘asymmetry’ between Napp and its competitors, and
finally, Napp’s intentions. To those matters we now turn.
The effect of Napp’s hospital pricing policy on
competition
|
||
|
||
68 |
||
|
||
|
||
“The overall strategic importance
of obtaining hospital usage was obvious, and was commonly accepted in the
industry. It meant that the key pain management specialists (clinicians
and nurses) would be endorsing our product in particular whenever
clinicians referred out patients by brand, or specialist nurses, in
constant contact with hospital practices, gave prescribing advice to GPs
this could potentially have a major influence on the GPs prescribing
habits.” (paragraph 34)
“The reality is that hospital
influence on the community prescribing is incredibly strong”
and that
“the influence of the hospital in this market is
profound”.
Among the reasons Mr Mountain
gives are that palliative care teams working in the community have been
trained in hospitals, GPs invariably follow the hospitals’ advice in
referral letters, and GPs will be anxious to secure consistency of
treatment as between primary and secondary care.
“Link depends entirely on
achieving a successful ‘conversion’ of a hospital to Zomorph as the basis
for establishing a reputation and sales in the surrounding community
segment of the market. This can only really be appreciated when one
considers the way in which we inform GPs and retail pharmacists about our
product.” (paragraph 28)
Mr Hartley goes on to explain
that Link’s strategy is first of all to secure a hospital contract. Once
that contract has been won, Link does not market directly in the community
segment but seeks to persuade the hospital authorities to inform GPs,
retail pharmacists and others that the switch to Zomorph has taken place,
explaining the advantages, and if possible recommending that it should be
prescribed as “Zomorph capsules”. In addition Link’s team spends time at
the hospitals carrying out training for the personnel who will be using
Zomorph on a day-to-day basis.
|
||
|
||
69 |
||
|
||
|
||
expensive and fruitless, and we
reject any suggestion by Napp to the contrary. We have no reason to doubt
the statement of Mr Mountain in his letter to the OFT of 3 November 2000
where he said, with reference to hospitals,
“There is only one way into this market and Napp have the key
to the gate”
70 |
||
|
||
|
||
additional hurdle to be overcome
by a new entrant, who already faces the development and promotional costs
associated with launching a new product, as well as the need to overcome
Napp’s strong first mover advantages, and the other barriers to entry we
have already mentioned.
“The unique barrier that we face
as a company trying to become known in this market place is Napp’s
practice of offering extreme discounts to hospitals making their product
almost free. At the levels of discount in question the average hospital
spend on MST tablets comes to something under £500 a year.”
71 |
||
|
||
|
||
adding Napp’s share of the
hospital segment to that part of the community segment which is directly
foreclosed by the follow-on effect of hospital prescriptions (or referral
letters) which directly refer to MST. That alone gives a direct
foreclosure of some 24 to 27 per cent of the relevant market (paragraphs
160 and 167 of the Decision).
|
||
|
||
72 |
||
|
||
|
||
of about 400. Although Link’s
share of the hospital segment has grown since the Director’s investigation
started from 1.7 per cent in 1999 to 4.3 per cent in 2000 and 7.3 per cent
in the first quarter of 2001, that is no doubt partly due to BIL’s
departure. We regard Link’s position as little more than a toehold –
acquired at considerable loss over several years – in the face of Napp’s
share of 93 per cent in that segment. Link’s share of the total market
(hospital and community segments together) was just under 4 per cent by
the first quarter of 2001, while Napp still had over 95 per cent of the
total.
|
||
|
||
73 |
||
|
||
|
||
pharmaceutical product coming out
of patent to maintain both its existing price and a virtual
monopoly market share for prolonged periods. On the contrary, in our view,
after patent expiry, one would normally expect some fall in price, or
market share, or both, as competitive forces come to bear on the
previously patented product. In the present case, that has not happened,
either to Napp’s prices, or to its market share, in the
community segment. It has not happened to Napp’s market share in the
hospital segment. Even allowing for the fact that in this case Napp’s
actual or potential competitors represent branded, rather than generic,
entry, in our judgment the overwhelming inference from the totality of the
evidence is that Napp’s prices in the community segment, and its market
shares in both the hospital and community segments, have been protected,
at least in part, by the foreclosure effects of Napp’s hospital discount
policy. Nor do we doubt that that was Napp’s intention: see paragraphs 307
et seq below.
Asymmetry: Napp’s advantages over its
competitors
|
||
|
||
74 |
||
|
||
|
||
segment can be made up on
subsequent sales in the community segment, Napp submits that there was in
fact a level playing field between itself and its
competitors.
“[The data] shows that even where
and when Zomorph succeeds in gaining access to hospitals, this has a
minimal impact on its market penetration among GPs.”
In relation to Oramorph the same report comments (p.
18):
“there are only limited linkages
between hospital and community sales of SRM. Most of the community market
that is currently “captive” to MST cannot be won simply by winning some
hospital contracts.”
|
||
|
||
75 |
||
|
||
|
||
“This is utterly mistaken. Where
patients were prescribed Oramorph SR in the hospital, we made every effort
to maximise the chances that patients would continue to be prescribed it
subsequently in the community, but we could never be sure this would
actually happen or to what extent. In many cases we found there was no
significant follow-on effect.”
“This is why Napp aggressively
defend the hospital business, and as a monopoly supplier why their pricing
is predatory.”
“on the contrary it is only the
application by Link of the various methods described above, which include,
above all, harnessing the reputation of the hospital specialists and the
PCG officials to communicate with GPs, nurses and retail pharmacists in
the community that achieves vital sales growth” (paragraph
37).
|
||
|
||
76 |
||
|
||
|
||
launch of Zomorph in 1997. It
cannot be known how long Link could have stayed in the market had it not
been for the present proceedings (and see paragraph 44
above).
The market since 1 March 2000
|
||
|
||
77 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
78 |
||
|
||
|
||
1999, to 91.9 per cent in 2000
and to 92.7 per cent in Q1 2001. That picture does not suggest to us that
there was any material weakening of Napp’s dominance during the period of
the infringement, nor that the playing field became materially more level
in the period since 1 March 2000.
Intention to eliminate competition
|
||
|
||
79 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
80 |
||
|
||
|
||
“I can only say to you from my
position that we always had a consistent strategy within the company. As
you well know, we were facing aggressive pricing discounts by our
competitors and they were constantly lowering their prices in the
hospitals, apart from also having lower prices in the community, but they
aggressively undercut our prices in hospitals and that has always been the
case with the competitors that we have faced. Our strategy over the years
to my mind has been absolutely consistent and you will see it, I think,
repeatedly in the documents, that our strategy was to match those prices.”
(Transcript, Day 1, p.19.)
When asked about the absence of documents since 1997, he
said:
MR BROGDEN ... “I do not know
whether I am right or wrong on this, but I can only attempt to explain it
by the sense that our strategy over the years has not changed, and our
strategy in terms of matching the prices that Boehringer created within
the hospital market has, to some extent been perpetuated with Link also
continuing to aggressively undercut our prices. In that sense there is
...
THE PRESIDENT: So in relation to
Link you have been following, broadly speaking, the same strategy that you
followed with Boehringer?
A. Yes, sir, broadly speaking, we
have been following the same strategy. There are differences, but those
are not of our making, and not our strategy.
Q. But the strategy has remained
consistent throughout?
A. The strategy has remained
consistent throughout, sir. If I may just say ...
Q. Of course.
A. ... because there is an
important difference, the one thing that Boehringer seemed to do to my
knowledge over the years was consistently submit tenders for the regional
health authority contracts. These are the big contracts. It seems, as we
have learned from our experience of late, that they [Link] have not
consistently done that, but our approach has always been consistent in the
sense of trying to match prices and submit tenders to hospitals.” (Day 1,
p 19)
“The tribunal may admit or
exclude evidence, whether or not the evidence was available to the
respondent when the disputed decision was taken and notwithstanding any
enactment or rule of law relating to the admissibility of evidence in
proceedings before a court.”
In the light of that Rule, in our
view it is open to the Director to rely on the documents disclosed to the
Tribunal even though they were not relied upon by the Director in the
Decision (i) as evidence tending to rebut assertions made by Napp in the
course of this appeal and (ii) as secondary support for the finding
already made by the Director in the Decision, that Napp’s intention was to
eliminate
81 |
||
|
||
|
||
competition. Napp has had a very
full opportunity to comment on the documents in question. We do not see
any unfairness to Napp if we permit the Director to rely on
them. |
||
|
||
“The launch of SRM-Rotard in
tablet strengths of 10mg, 30mg, 60mg and 100mg, in identical colours to
MST CONTINUS Tablets, is clearly the most important issue with which we
now have to deal... We have agreed internally that we will match (beat, if
necessary) their prices to hospitals and hospices.”
“Farmitalia’s approach has been
to concentrate on hospitals and hospices by offering extremely low prices,
which we have been forced to match in order to retain this important and
influential business.” (year-end report for December 1992).
and that:
“an aggressive pricing policy is
essential to prevent the adoption and acceptance of new competitors.”
(June 1993 mid-year report)
“The effect, however, would be to
deflate the vital element of Boehringer’s promotional strategy and limit
their opportunities to give Oramorph SR early success. It would also
reaffirm that this is our market and any “would be” competitor may hurt us
but will gain nothing for themselves.”
“The above action is both
immediate and uncompromising as a response to Boehringer’s threat, and
will hopefully signal to them that we are NOT leaving this market
open to them...”
“Clearly the 90% discount option
would send an unequivocal message to Boehringer that there was no place
for them in this market. We do not of course know what their
82 |
||
|
||
|
||
intentions are and can only
assume that they would not be prepared to lose money in order to penetrate
the market.”
Mr Smailes’ proposal was to
“offer 80% discount prices and review the situation in the light of the
outcome.” Mr Brogden responded to Mr Smailes’ memo on 20 June 1994 in the
following terms:
“I know there is a school of
thought that argues that we should ‘stuff Boehringer’ by quoting
substantial discounts, eg, 90%. However, I don’t want to simply win the
battle and lose the war by getting stuck with such low prices that our
hospital sales have no absolute value (other than referral). It’s the
usual difficult balancing act. I’d be inclined to accept the proposal of
80% made by Chris providing that the contracts come up in such a sequence
as to allow us to drop our price if we should fall at the first hurdle. If
three significant contracts have to be completed at the same time
then I would consider moving to 85%. Incidentally, Arthur, these judgments
have to be made in relation to the cost of goods and you should encourage
Chris to include these in future.”
“Chris I’d be inclined not to prevaricate. Simply match the
prices.” |
||
|
||
“In volume terms MST CONTINUS
Tablets have done surprisingly well. Our aggressive stance towards
Boehringer’s pricing is certainly working although, of course, reducing
our overall sales and profit. I have already reported that our discounts
are around 80% on tender business ... Perhaps more significantly though we
are preventing them from getting a “toe-hold” in the GP
market.”
“The cost of a drug is now the
prime consideration with many if not most doctors. Unfortunately our major
promoted products are highly exposed: MST continues to suffer severe price
erosion from Boehringer’s efforts. Recently Oramorph SR was offered on
contract at 97.5% discount compared with MST.”
The report goes on to identify under the heading “Competitor
Activity”,
“(i) the continuing need to keep
Boehringer at bay. This focuses particularly on the hospital contract
market and those retailers supplying hospices.”
|
||
|
||
83 |
||
|
||
|
||
“The projected decline in cash
sales for the tablets is in part due to the continued need for aggressive
contract pricing to match Boehringer’s (Oramorph SR) ...”
“1. Perhaps understandably, they
[BIL] felt hospital/hospice endorsement was very important to their market
entry and aggressively undercut our own contract prices. As you
appreciate, hospital endorsement (usage) can influence greatly the general
practitioner and to prevent them gaining this foothold we also reduced our
contract prices. They have now stabilised at the ludicrous figures you see
in the table and whilst they are still half our price, the total value of
the purchases by an individual hospital are so small as to largely negate
any desire or reason for a hospital to move away from MST
CONTINUS.
2. The above strategy [by BIL]
was coupled with lower basic NHS price than MST. There are two reasons.
Firstly, many hospitals appreciate the influence that their choice of drug
has on the community general practitioner and believe therefore that they
have a responsibility to make their choice of product with some regard to
what the wider community will have to pay. Thus Boehringer use the lower
Basic NHS price to persuade the hospital pharmacist – “not only will you
pay less, but by following you the community, general practitioner will
also pay less”. Secondly, of course, the lower basic NHS price is simply
placed in front of the general practitioner as a money saving device
against the practice budgets.”
“Our morphine preparations have
done considerably better than anticipated. This reflects the introduction
of MXL once-a-day morphine ... We have been very successful in containing
our competitors though not without a continued erosion of prices when
trying to keep them out of the hospital market.”
|
||
|
||
84 |
||
|
||
|
||
“to reaffirm that this is our
market and that any ‘would be’ competitor may hurt us but gain nothing for
themselves.”
and
“to send an unequivocal message
to Boehringer that there is no place for them in this
market.”
|
||
|
||
85 |
||
|
||
|
||
96 per cent of the community
segment, Mr Manners makes no reference to any internal documents which
support his description of Napp’s hospital pricing policy. Those we have
seen in the course of these proceedings confirm that it was not simply a
case of “making extra sales”, but of a consistent policy of excluding
competitors from the hospital segment.
Conclusion on Napp’s net revenue
defence
|
||
|
||
86 |
||
|
||
|
||
or gain market share in, the
hospital segment and, ultimately, in the community segment of the market,
were placed at a significant competitive disadvantage by Napp’s hospital
discounting policy; (c) Napp’s intention was, so far as possible, to
eliminate competition by preventing or hindering market entry into both
the hospital and the community segments; (d) Napp’s primary motivation was
not to make “extra sales”, nor to make “an incremental profit” in
recognition of the “follow-on benefits” accruing from hospital contracts,
but to deny to its competitors a key means of entering the market for oral
sustained release morphine in the United Kingdom through the gateway of
the hospital segment.
|
||
|
||
87 |
||
|
||
|
||
over 90 per cent of the market
may commit an abuse if it selectively cuts prices deliberately to match
those of a competitor, even if it is not shown that the undertaking has
priced below total costs. In that case the dominant undertaking had
eliminated the principal, and possibly the only means of competition open
to its sole rival, thereby maintaining higher prices in the area not
threatened by competition. There was a market share of over 90 per cent,
and an intention to eliminate competition (paragraphs 117 and 118 of the
judgment). As Mr Fennelly pointed out in his opinion (at paragraphs 135
and 137) it was a case of a superdominant undertaking which had
selectively targeted competitors with discriminatory price cuts,
implemented with relative autonomy from costs, with the aim of eliminating
all competition.
Napp’s other arguments
|
||
|
||
88 |
||
|
||
|
||
[...] [in excess of 90] per cent
are not normal in hospital tenders; (ii) that such discounts have been
granted selectively only where Napp has been faced by a competitor; and
(iii) that the resulting difference between what the hospital pays and the
normal NHS list price is exceptional – in some cases over 2000 per cent –
as the Director finds at paragraphs 198 to 200 of the Decision (see
Section VIII below). Perhaps more significantly, we do not regard it as
“normal” for prices to hospitals to remain below direct costs for many
years. For the reasons already given, we find that the below-cost pricing
in question was not a ‘normal’ commercial response but the response of a
superdominant undertaking aiming to eliminate competition. Nothing in the
structure of the NHS compelled Napp to act as it did.
|
||
|
||
89 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
90 |
||
|
||
|
||
“selectively supplying sustained
release morphine tablets and capsules to customers in the hospital segment
at lower prices than to customers in the community segment.”
Although the Director has, in the
Decision, rightly criticised the extent of the differential between
Napp’s prices in the hospital and community segments, it does not seem to
us that, in the Decision, the Director has alleged that supplying the
hospital segment at lower prices than the community segment is, of
itself, an abuse. The Director has not addressed to us any detailed
argument on this issue, nor made specific reference to subparagraph (i) of
paragraph 236. If and in so far as the word “selectively” in subparagraph
(i) is intended to add anything, the “selective” nature of Napp’s
discounts is already referred to in subparagraphs (ii) and (iii) of
paragraph 236. It seems to us, therefore, that sufficient grounds have not
been shown for upholding paragraph 236(a)(i) of the Decision if and in so
far as that subparagraph is intended to identify an element of the abuse
not otherwise covered by the rest of paragraph
236(a). |
||
|
||
91 |
||
|
||
|
||
Conclusion
VIII — ABUSE: EXCESSIVE
PRICES
A: ARGUMENTS OF THE PARTIES
Napp’s arguments in the notice of appeal
353. The essence of
Napp’s case is summarised in the notice of appeal as follows:
“Napp has not charged excessive
prices for MST. The price of MST is set in accordance with the PPRS, and
is a reasonable price, having regard to the objects of the PPRS, and the
fact that its terms are calculated, inter alia, to provide an appropriate
incentive to Napp and to other companies to invest in R&D to secure a
new generation of drugs for supply to the NHS.” (paragraph
4.1(ii)(a))
Napp relies very largely on
Nera’s report of 29 May 2001, Napp: Analysis of OFT Decision on Excess
Pricing for MST (A 106) and a paper of 24 May 2001 prepared by Napp
entitled Evidence on Other Therapeutic Markets, (A
112).
“… over the life cycle of the
product as a whole, provides pharmaceutical firms … with the appropriate
incentive to invest in such R&D, education, training and promotion to
the extent that consumers collectively are willing to fund such
investment. Any such competitive price will take account of the ex ante
uncertainty as to whether a particular product will succeed.” (notice
of appeal, paragraph 5.21)
|
||
|
||
92 |
||
|
||
|
||
incorrect to suggest, at
paragraph 130 of the Decision that the limits set by the PPRS are “not
restrictive”. The pharmaceutical industry is a relatively high risk
industry because of the amount of R&D required and the uncertainty of
finding successful drugs. Napp’s overall rates of return are well within
reasonable limits for an industry of this kind.
357. In these
circumstances, says Napp, only a “portfolio-based” approach such as that
of the PPRS, which assesses profitability across a range of investments
made in conditions of “ex ante uncertainty”, can evaluate whether a firm
is enjoying excessive profitability. According to Napp, both European
Community and United Kingdom law recognise the importance of portfolio
pricing: see Advocate General Reischl in Case 262/81 Coditel II
[1982] ECR 3381 at pp 3411, 3412 and Monopolies and Mergers Commission
Report, “The Supply of Recorded Music: a report on the Supply in the
United Kingdom of Pre-recorded compact discs, vinyl discs and tapes
containing music” (1994).
|
||
|
||
93 |
||
|
||
|
||
MST was, secondly, considering
Napp’s expected volume of sales, and, thirdly, assessing how much profit
Napp needs to make in order to fund its ongoing research
activities.
94 |
||
|
||
|
||
strength enables it to attract a
premium over other brands, as the Director accepts. Nothing in the
Director’s analysis serves to show that MST’s legitimate brand premium is
excessive, or by how much. In addition, Napp points out that the Director
has miscalculated the price of Morcap SR. Further the Director has
misunderstood the nature of Napp’s export sales. Napp is merely a contract
manufacturer and has no involvement or risk in the marketing of the
product outside the United Kingdom. Comparisons with Napp’s other NHS
products are not meaningful either. |
||
|
||
363. Finally, Napp points out
that other benchmarks investigated by the Director failed to support his
case. A comparison with similar products in other EU member states did not
show that Napp’s prices were excessive. Nor did an investigation into the
return on capital employed earned by Napp reveal that Napp’s prices were
excessive as compared with other firms. Nothing in Community law, notably
Case 27/76 United Brands v Commission [1978] ECR 207 (“United
Brands”), supports the Director’s approach. |
||
|
||
The Director’s arguments in the
defence
“16. In essence, the Director
General’s case is that Napp charges excessively low and/or discriminatory
prices in the hospital segment and thereby sustains very high prices and
market share in the community segment of the market. These two aspects are
accordingly interlinked. Napp’s pricing practices have the effect of
placing significant obstacles against the successful entry of competitors,
and in consequence serve to preserve its quasi-monopoly position in the
community segment of the market and enable it to continue to charge prices
for MST higher than could be sustained in the absence of that
quasi-monopoly position ie competitive prices …
17. Accordingly, the Director
General does not seek to condemn the prices in the community segment in
isolation; in other words, if his case should fail as regards the
exclusionary character of Napp’s pricing practice in the hospital segment,
he does not contend that the prices in the community segment violate the
Chapter II prohibition simply because of their absolute
level.”
“As stated above, it is the
Director General’s case that Napp’s conduct has had the effect of
excluding competitors from the hospital segment, thereby foreclosing the
essential gateway for entry to the community segment. As a result Napp has
retained its quasi-monopoly position in the community segment and has been
able to charge quasi-monopoly prices. In those circumstances, the charging
of prices, which are |
||
|
||
95 |
||
|
||
|
||
higher than Napp would be able to
charge in a competitive market, constitutes an abuse.”
The Director relies on United Brands, at pages 301 and
302 of that judgment.
|
||
|
||
96 |
||
|
||
|
||
lower its community prices. Napp
might have decided that it was more profitable to maintain its community
prices for some time, even though this would have lost market share,
before responding with lower community prices. Napp suggests that any
reduction in its community prices would most likely have occurred after 30
March 2001.
|
||
|
||
98 |
||
|
||
|
||
The Director’s response to the alleged change of
case
|
||
|
||
99 |
||
|
||
|
||
“The essential significance of
Napp’s exclusionary conduct (both before and after 1 March 2000) to the
finding of excessive prices is that it provides a solid basis on which to
conclude that, in the absence of such conduct, there would have been
effective price competition in this market as from 1 March
2000.”
B: LAW
“directly or indirectly imposing unfair ... selling
prices”. |
||
|
||
100 |
||
|
||
|
||
“248 The imposition by an
undertaking in a dominant position directly or indirectly of unfair
purchase or selling prices is an abuse to which exception can be taken
under Article 82 of the Treaty.
249 It is
advisable therefore to ascertain whether the dominant undertaking has made
use of the opportunities arising out of its dominant position in such a
way as to reap trading benefits which it would not have reaped if there
had been normal and sufficiently effective competition.
250 In this
case charging a price which is excessive because it has no reasonable
relation to the economic value of the product supplied would be such an
abuse.
251 This
excess could, inter alia, be determined objectively if it were
possible for it to be calculated by making a comparison between the
selling price of the product in question and its cost of production, which
would disclose the amount of the profit margin; however the Commission has
not done this since it has not analysed UBC’s costs
structure.
252 The
questions therefore to be determined are whether the difference between
the costs actually incurred and the price actually charged is excessive,
and, if the answer to this question is in the affirmative, whether a price
has been imposed which is either unfair in itself or when compared to
competing products.
253 Other ways
may be devised – and economic theorists have not failed to think up
several – of selecting the rules for determining whether the price of a
product is unfair”
C: FINDINGS
The abuse as found in the Decision
|
||
|
||
101 |
||
|
||
|
||
“if it is above that which would
exist in a competitive market and where it is clear that high profits will
not stimulate successful new entry within a reasonable period. Therefore,
to show that prices are excessive, it must be demonstrated that (i) prices
are higher than would be expected in a competitive market, and (ii) there
is no effective competitive pressure to bring them down to competitive
levels, nor is there likely to be.”
— Napp’s prices in
the community segment are typically around [...] [between 30 to 50] per
cent higher than its competitors.
— Apart from certain
across-the-board reductions applying to the pharmaceutical industry as a
whole under the PPRS, Napp’s price in the community segment has remained
the same since the launch of MST in 1980, (save, as we understand it, for
one increase in 1983) notwithstanding the expiry of its formulation patent
in 1992.
— Napp’s list price
(less wholesale discount) in the community segment of the market is on
average over 1400 per cent higher than its price in the hospital segment
of the market for 10mg, 30mg, 60mg, and 100 mg tablets, where Napp faces
competition.
— At Napp’s highest
level of discount, the list price in the community segment is on some
tablets over 2000 per cent higher than Napp’s hospital
prices.
— Napp’s prices in
the community segment are over 500 per cent higher than its prices for
export on a contract manufacture basis. As we understand it, MST faces
competition in export markets. |
||
|
||
102 |
||
|
||
|
||
— Napp’s gross
profit margin on sales to the community segment is [...] [in excess of 80]
per cent, compared with a margin of around [...] [between 30 and 50] per
cent on Napp’s other products sold to the NHS.
— Napp’s gross
profit margin of [...] [in excess of 80] per cent on sales to the
community segment compares with a gross profit margin of [...] [less than
70] per cent for Napp’s next most profitable competitor. If Napp’s
manufacturing margin is recalculated on the basis of the costs of its next
most profitable competitor, Napp’s gross margin becomes [...] [less than
90] per cent compared with that competitor’s [...] [less than 70] per
cent.
|
||
|
||
103 |
||
|
||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||
community segment of some 96 per
cent. Those facts also support the proposition that Napp’s community
prices, unlike its hospital prices, have not been subject to competitive
pressure, as the Director found in paragraph 213 of the
Decision.
Napp’s prices (£ per pack of 60)
NHS List NHS price to
Average
Lowest
Export price
price to the the community
hospital price hospital price community less wholesale
discount |
||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||
5mg
4.30
3.76
10mg
7.17
6.27
15mg
12.57
11.00
30mg
17.22
15.07
60mg
33.58
29.38
100mg
53.16
46.52 |
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||
200mg
106.34
93.05 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||
104 |
||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||
|
||
most profitable competitor. In
addition, Napp faced no competitive pressure on its prices in the
community segment, had no patent protection, and enjoyed a market share of
96 per cent throughout.
Napp’s defence based on the PPRS
105 |
||
|
||
|
||
cannot be judged without knowing
the size of Napp’s initial investment in that product and its expected
volume of sales; (ii) that the PPRS is a sufficient control over the price
of MST; and (iii) that the Director has failed to take into account the
need for “portfolio” pricing: see paragraphs 353 to 361
above.
|
||
|
||
106 |
||
|
||
|
||
“—Secure the provision of safe
and effective medicines for the NHS at reasonable prices.
- Promote a strong
and profitable pharmaceutical industry capable of such sustained research
and development as should lead to the future availability of new and
improved medicines.
- Encourage the
efficient and competitive development and supply of medicines to
pharmaceutical markets to this and other countries.”
|
||
|
||
107 |
||
|
||
|
||
which we are required to consider
when deciding whether there is an abuse of a dominant position under
section 18 of the Act. In our view, it is not appropriate, when deciding
whether an undertaking has abused a dominant position by charging
excessive prices in a particular market, to take into account the
reasonableness or otherwise of its profits on other, unspecified, markets
comprised in some wider but undefined “portfolio” unrelated to the market
in which dominance exists.
“The PPRS does not guarantee a
company a particular level of sales, or a particular level of profit
associated with those sales, for a number of reasons…”
“… a company facing competing
products may not be in a strong position to increase prices as a way of
generating additional revenue, unless it has other products in its
portfolio facing little therapeutic competition.”
|
||
|
||
108 |
||
|
||
|
||
the remarks of Advocate General
Reischl in Coditel II, nor the Monopolies and Mergers Commission
Report The Supply of Recorded Music, seem to us to be relevant to
the present case.
|
||
|
||
109 |
||
|
||
|
||
the public interest arguments may
be for the PPRS, those arguments do not seem to us to be relevant to the
justification of an excessive price in circumstances where it is the
undertaking’s own anti-competitive activities which have, to a material
extent, prevented any significant competitive pressure being brought to
bear on the price in question. To seek to justify such a price on the
basis of the PPRS is in our view to move wholly outside the objectives of
the PPRS and to bring the PPRS into potential conflict with the
Act. |
||
|
||
“These margins [in the community
segment] result from a lack of competition in the community segment which,
in turn, results from the anti-competitive effects of Napp’s discounting
behaviour in the hospital segment.” (paragraph 151)
“Napp cannot therefore justify a
policy of loss leading [in the hospital sector] except in so far as
cutting hospital prices below AVC denies a competitor the opportunity to
establish itself in the community sector and thereby allows Napp to
continue to earn high margins in that sector.” (paragraph
194)
“That Napp can earn high
compensating margins in the community segment ... is because its discount
policy in the hospital segment has hindered competition in the community
segment. ... The object and effect of the low pricing in the hospital
segment is indeed to protect and take advantage of Napp’s near monopolist
position [in the community segment].” (paragraph 195)
“It is only in the community
segment where buyers are less price sensitive and where there is an
absence of effective price competition, partly as a consequence of Napp’s
conduct, that Napp can sustain a premium of 40 per cent on competitors.”
(paragraph 211)
“That Napp has sustained these
higher margins without stimulating successful new entry is due, at least
in part, to its exclusionary pricing policies in the hospital segment of
the market.” (paragraph 228)
“Napp has maintained excessively
high margins on the sale of MST in the community segment of the market
without effective competition from successful new entry. This is due, at
least in part, to Napp’s exclusionary pricing practices in the hospital
segment.” (paragraph 232) |
||
|
||
110 |
||
|
||
|
||
“The lack of successful entry in
this case is in part due to Napp’s exclusionary practices in the hospital
segment of the market.” (paragraph 225)
111 |
||
|
||
|
||
The Director’s alleged “change of
case”
|
||
|
||
112 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
113 |
||
|
||
|
||
Conclusion
|
||
|
||
114 |
||
|
||
|
||
IX — THE
PENALTY
A: INTENTIONALLY OR
NEGLIGENTLY
Arguments of the
parties
445. Napp further submits, in reliance on the
witness statements of Mr Manners and Mr Brogden, that:
“(i) Napp has at all material
times believed that the PPRS was effective to prevent it from charging
excessive prices and that, provided that Napp observed the terms of the
PPRS, its pricing of MST to the NHS would not be regarded as
excessive.
(ii) Napp has at all material
times believed that it was normal and acceptable commercial practice for a
supplier of a leading brand of a pharmaceutical product, facing
competition from new entrants, and with no patent protection, to maintain
the NHS list price of its product, and to offer differential discounts to
different buyers according to their willingness to pay, in the manner and
to the extent that Napp has offered discounts against the list price of
MST.
(iii) Napp did not believe that,
by offering substantial discounts against the list price of MST to
hospital buyers, it would thereby incur incremental losses. It believed
that sales of MST to hospital buyers would result in incremental profits
to Napp, when account was taken of the effects which hospital sales could
be expected to have in maintaining or increasing sales of MST in the
community segment of the market. Prior to the commissioning of the
Internet Survey at document A18, Napp did not, however, seek to quantify
the extent of any such linkages between hospital and community sales. Napp
believed that it was normal commercial practice to offer discounts to
hospitals which took account of linkages between hospital and community
sales. Nor did Napp have any reason to believe |
||
|
||
115 |
||
|
||
|
||
otherwise: Napp observed that
other firms were offering discounts which were suggestive that those other
firms were also competing on that basis. Napp did not believe that it
could expect to secure greater linkages between hospital and community
sales than other suppliers of oral sustained release
morphine.”
(paragraph 5.58 of the notice of appeal, as
substituted.)
|
||
|
||
116 |
||
|
||
|
||
of the Act. Paragraph 7.3 of the
Director’s Guidance as to the Appropriate Amount of the Penalty
(OFT 423) (“the Director’s Guidance”) states that “Mitigating
factors include: … infringements which are committed negligently rather
than intentionally.”
450. The Director
submits that it is not necessary for an undertaking to have been aware
that it was infringing the Act for an infringement to be regarded as
having been committed intentionally. It is sufficient that it could not
have been unaware that the contested conduct had as its object or effect,
or could have had as its effect, the restriction of competition: e.g. by
way of example Case T-65/89 BPB Industries and British Gypsum v
Commission [1993] ECR II-389, paragraph 165; see also: Case T-77/92
Parker Pen v Commission [1994] ECR II-549, paragraph 81; Case
100/80 Musique Diffusion Française v Commission [1983] ECR 1825,
paragraph 112; Case 85/76 Hoffman La Roche v Commission, cited
above, at paragraph 39.
Law
|
||
|
||
117 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
118 |
||
|
||
|
||
Findings on intentionally or
negligently
Discounts to hospitals
|
||
|
||
119 |
||
|
||
|
||
negligently”. As we have just
held, the Director was not, at this stage of the analysis, obliged to
specify whether he considered the infringement to be intentional or merely
negligent. |
||
|
||
“243. Napp was similarly aware of
the strategic importance of the hospital segment for new competitors and
potential entrants. It must therefore have been aware that its discounts
to hospitals would have the effect of reducing the ability of competitors
to gain market share in the hospital and community segments of the market,
and could lead them to exit the market altogether. That this was Napp’s
intention is shown the more clearly by the fact that its prices to
hospitals were below direct cost and by its having adjusted discounts on
particular products and in respect of supplies to particular hospital
regions according to the amount of competition it faced.
244. The Director is satisfied
therefore that Napp’s conduct had as its object the restriction of
competition. He is equally satisfied that Napp was aware that its actions
would be, or, at the very least, would be reasonably be likely to be,
restrictive of competition, but was still prepared to carry them out.
Furthermore, contrary to Napp’s representations, Napp cannot have been
unaware of the exceptional magnitude of the discounts it was offering to
hospitals or of the asymmetry between its position in the market and that
of its competitors. It must therefore have been aware that it would not be
possible for competitors to engage in similar pricing behaviour over the
long term.”
|
||
|
||
|
||
120 |
||
|
||
|
||
infringement. We do not regard
sustained pricing below direct cost by a superdominant enterprise enjoying
a virtual monopoly 20 years after the launch of the product as in any
sense “normal competition” or “legitimate commercial usage”, as those
terms are understood in Community or domestic competition
law.
Excessive prices
“246. Napp has maintained high
prices in the community segment of the relevant market in the full
knowledge of its own very high market share, its profit margins on such
sales, its competitors’ prices, the preference for its brand on the part
of the GPs, and their lack of price sensitivity. The Director therefore
considers that Napp’s infringement in respect of its excessive prices to
the community was, for the purposes of section 36 of the Act, intentional
or, at the very least, negligent.”
121 |
||
|
||
|
||
above the levels that would
prevail in conditions of normal competition. In this case Napp knew that
it had a virtual monopoly in the community segment. Napp also knew that
the price of MST was not subject to competitive pressure in the community
segment. Napp, however, maintained the price of MST knowing that that
price was (i) around 40 per cent above that of its competitors; (ii) on
average over 1400 per cent above its price to hospitals on 10mg, 30mg,
60mg and 100mg tablets; and (iii) up to [...] [in excess of 500] per cent
above its export prices on those tablets. Napp also knew that its gross
profit margin was some [...] [in excess of 80]per cent, well above its
average NHS margin.
122 |
||
|
||
|
||
to 427 above. Moreover the fact
that the Director’s case has developed in the course of the proceedings
does not alter the fact that, objectively speaking, Napp maintained prices
in the community segment that it at least ought to have known were well
above competitive levels and protected from competition. We do not accept
that the question of “intentionally or negligently” under section 36(3) of
the Act depends on whether or not the undertaking was told by the Director
how to conduct its business. In the present case reference to United
Brands, at paragraphs 248 to 253 of the judgment, cited above, would
or should have put Napp on notice of the possibility that it was reaping
trading benefits in the community segment “which it could not have reaped
if there had been normal and sufficient competition”.
B: THE AMOUNT OF THE PENALTY
The Director’s Guidance
“The twin objectives of the
Director’s policy on financial penalties are to impose penalties on
infringing undertakings which reflect the seriousness of the infringement
and to ensure that the threat of penalties will deter undertakings from
engaging in anti-competitive practices. The Director therefore intends,
where appropriate, to impose financial penalties which are severe, in
particular in respect of agreements between undertakings which fix prices
or share markets and other cartel activities, as well as serious abuses of
a dominant position, which the Director considers are among the most
serious infringements caught under the Act. The deterrent is not aimed
solely at the undertakings which are subject to the decision, but also at
other undertakings which might be considering activities that are contrary
to the Chapter I and Chapter II prohibitions.” |
||
|
||
123 |
||
|
||
|
||
“2.3 The starting point for
determining the level of financial penalty which will be imposed on an
undertaking is calculated by applying a percentage rate to the “relevant
turnover” of the undertaking, up to a maximum of 10%. The “relevant
turnover” is the turnover of the undertaking in the relevant product
market and relevant geographic market affected by the infringement in the
last financial year. This may include turnover generated outside the
United Kingdom if the relevant geographic market for the relevant product
is wider than the United Kingdom.
2.4 The actual percentage rate
which will be applied to the “relevant turnover” will depend upon the
nature of the infringement. The more serious the infringement, the higher
the percentage rate is likely to be. Price-fixing or market-sharing
agreements and other cartel activities are among the most serious
infringements caught under the Chapter I prohibition. Conduct which
infringes the Chapter II prohibition and which by virtue of the
undertaking’s dominant position and the nature of the conduct has, or is
likely to have a particularly serious effect on competition, for example,
predatory pricing, is also one of the most serious infringements under the
Act. The starting point for such activities and conduct will be calculated
by applying a percentage likely to be at or near 10% of the “relevant
turnover” of the infringing undertakings.”
“2.8 The penalty figure reached
after the calculations in steps 1 and 2 may be adjusted as appropriate to
achieve the policy objectives, outlined in paragraph 1.8 above, in
particular, of imposing penalties on infringing undertakings in order to
deter undertakings from engaging in anti-competitive practices. The
deterrent is not aimed solely at the undertakings which are subject to the
decision, but also at other undertakings which might be considering
activities which are contrary to the Chapter I and Chapter II
prohibitions. Considerations at this stage may include, for example, the
Director’s estimate of the gain made or likely to be |
||
|
||
124 |
||
|
||
|
||
made by the infringing
undertaking from the infringement. Where relevant, the Director’s estimate
would account for any gains which might accrue to the undertaking in other
product or geographic markets as well as the “relevant” market under
consideration. The assessment of the need to adjust the penalty will be
made on a case by case basis for each individual infringing
undertaking.
2.9 This step may result in a
substantial adjustment of the financial penalty calculated at the earlier
steps. The consequence may be that the penalty which is imposed is much
larger than would otherwise have been imposed. The result of any one of
steps 2 or 3 above or 4 below may well be to take the penalty over 10% of
the “relevant turnover” identified at step 1, but the overall cap on
penalties is 10% of the “section 36(8) turnover” referred to in step 5
below and must not be exceeded.”
“3. The turnover of an undertaking for the purposes of section
36(8) is:
(1) the applicable
turnover for the business year preceding the date when the infringement
ended;
(2) where the length
of the infringement is more than 12 months, in addition the amount of the
applicable turnover for the business year preceding that identified under
paragraph (1) which bears the same proportion to the applicable turnover
for that business year as the period by which the length of infringement
exceeds 12 months bears to 12 months; and
(3) where the length
of the infringement is more than 24 months, in addition the amount of the
applicable turnover for the business year preceding that identified under
paragraph (2) which bears the same proportion to the applicable turnover
for that business year as the period by which the length of infringement
exceeds 24 months bears to 12 months;
save that the amount added under
paragraph (2) or (3) shall not exceed the amount of the applicable
turnover for the preceding business year in
question.” |
||
|
||
125 |
||
|
||
|
||
The Director’s approach in the
Decision
“249. The relevant product market
affected by the infringements is the supply of sustained release morphine
tablets and capsules in the UK. Napp’s turnover in the relevant product
market in the year ending 31 December 2000 was £[...] million. The
Director has taken this as the relevant turnover for the purposes of
calculating the starting point.
250. The actual
percentage rate applied to the relevant turnover depends upon the nature
of the infringement. The more serious the infringement, the higher the
percentage rate is likely to be.
251. Napp has
supplied sustained release morphine tablets and capsules to hospitals at
significant discounts with the object and effect of preventing competitors
from increasing their share of the relevant market and deterring new
entry. Napp has further targeted its discounts at those areas where it
faced or expected competition. The Director considers that Napp’s discount
policy directly restricted competition in at least a quarter of the
relevant market and indirectly impaired competition in the whole of the
relevant market. These discounts have therefore seriously disadvantaged
Napp’s competitors in competing for hospital sales and thereby further
restricted and diminished competition in the hospital segment of the
market. Furthermore, the hospital segment of the market is of considerable
strategic importance for competitors wishing to increase sales in the
larger community segment of the market. Hence Napp’s discounts to
hospitals have restricted and diminished competition in both the hospital
and the community segments of the market.
252. Napp faces very
little competition in the community segment of the market and the barriers
to entry are high. Napp’s prices to the community are typically some 40%
higher than those of its competitors and, in most cases, over 1000% higher
than the prices it charges to hospitals. They are also between [...] [in
excess of 100%] and [...] [less than 700%] higher than its prices for
export. In addition, its gross profit margins on community sales are in
excess of [...][80%] compared to average NHS margins of around 40%. The
result of Napp’s conduct is a serious distortion of competition, and a
considerable excess cost to the NHS and so to the taxpayer.
253. Sustained
release morphine tablets and capsules are supplied for use in the final
product market, rather than as an intermediate good, and the cost is borne
by the taxpayer. The effects are therefore widespread.
254. The Director
therefore concludes that, contrary to Napp’s submissions, Napp has
committed a serious infringement of the Chapter II prohibition and has
taken as the starting point for determining the penalty 8% of the relevant
turnover.”
126 |
||
|
||
|
||
“257. The penalty figure reached
after the calculations in steps 1 and 2 may be adjusted as appropriate to
achieve the Director’s policy objectives of reflecting the seriousness of
the infringement and deterrence. As regards the latter, the deterrent is
not aimed solely at the infringing undertaking but also at other
undertakings which might be considering activities contrary to the
Act.
258. The Director
considers that it is appropriate to make an adjustment to the penalty in
order in particular to achieve his policy objective of deterrence. To
achieve this objective, the Director has decided that in the present case
the basis for the adjustment should be his estimate of Napp’s gain from
the infringements.
259. It is
impossible to estimate with certainty how much lower Napp’s profits would
have been, or would now be, on sales of sustained release morphine tablets
and capsules in the UK in the absence of the infringements. It is however
clear that prices in the community segment of the market are, and have
been throughout the period of the infringement, excessive and typically
40% higher than the prices charged by Napp’s competitors. Moreover, it
could be expected that were it not for the infringements, not only would
Napp’s community prices have been lower but the volume and value of its
sales in the market as a whole would also have been, and would now be,
lower. However, it is likely that Napp’s revenues from hospital sales,
representing on average 15% of the market by volume and less than 1% by
value, have been less than they would otherwise have been.
260. On the basis of
these findings, the Director estimates that Napp’s likely gain from the
infringements is, at the very least, £2m. The Director considers that this
figure probably underestimates Napp’s gain from the infringements but is
satisfied that it is appropriate in this case to adjust the penalty by
this amount in order to meet the Director’s policy objectives on
penalties. In reaching this conclusion, the Director has had regard both
to Napp’s turnover on the relevant market and to the fact that Napp’s
profits are subject to taxation. Following Step 3, the penalty is
therefore adjusted to £2.92m.”
|
||
|
||
127 |
||
|
||
|
||
“265. The final amount of any
penalty imposed under section 36 may not exceed 10% of the turnover of the
undertaking calculated in accordance with the Competition Act 1998
(Determination of Turnover for Penalties) Order. The UK turnover of Napp
Pharmaceutical Holdings Limited in 2000 amounted to £51.2 and in 1999 to
£53.9m. The length of the infringement exceeds 12 months by 30 days, so
that the turnover for the purposes of section 36(8) of the Act is £51.2m +
30/365 of £53.9m, i.e. £55.6m. The calculated penalty does not exceed 10%
of this figure.”
Arguments of the parties
|
||
|
||
128 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
129 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
130 |
||
|
||
|
||
of community sales of 5.25 per
cent. It is implausible that the reputation effect would account for only
a further 1.75 per cent of the market (over 3 years) to make up Napp’s
figure of 7 per cent. As to the Director’s assumptions, Napp says that the
ratio of hospital to community sales suggests a high ‘linkage’ in favour
of Link of about 1:2.8, which undermines the Director’s case on the lack
of “follow-on effect”.
Findings
General observations
131 |
||
|
||
|
||
to 31 March 2001. It is clear
from that Order that Parliament intended that it is the overall turnover
of the undertaking concerned, rather than its turnover in the products
affected by the infringement, which is the final determinant for the
amount of the penalty. As the Director points out in the Guidance,
any other approach would mean that abuses by powerful companies in small
relevant markets might not be appropriately sanctioned.
|
||
|
||
132 |
||
|
||
|
||
The issue of duration in relation to hospital
pricing
“The gain” at Step 3
133 |
||
|
||
|
||
given case, what the gain is.
That difficulty is illustrated by the present case. The Director did not
disclose his original calculations which, according to him, showed a gain
to Napp of £2 million. Since then, in the notice of appeal and the
defence, and in a flurry of calculations and counter calculations
exchanged between the parties in the days before the hearing, various
different hypotheses and scenarios have been put forward by both sides.
The Director’s final figure (still £2 million) is some 100 per cent above
Napp’s final figure (some £1 million). The major difference between the
parties are their different assumptions as to the rate at which Napp would
have lost market share in the community segment if it had not priced below
cost in the hospital segment from 1 March 2000 – 7 per cent over 3 years,
according to Napp, and 25 per cent over 2 years, according to the
Director.
|
||
|
||
134 |
||
|
||
|
||
Aggravation under Step 4
|
||
|
||
135 |
||
|
||
|
||
continuing with infringing
conduct after a clear warning of the illegality of the conduct in question
could be an aggravating circumstance. Otherwise, the temptation might be
to continue the illegal conduct for as long as possible, in the hope that
the resulting commercial gain would outweigh any subsequent penalty. Nor,
in our view, does such a possibility of taking account of such an
aggravating circumstance necessarily contravene the “rights of the
defence”. The undertaking may still vigorously defend itself before the
Director. The ‘aggravating circumstance’ is simply that continuing with
conduct after an express warning of its illegality may be a worse offence
than it would have been if no warning had been given.
|
||
|
||
136 |
||
|
||
|
||
and instead proposed a direction
to the effect that the NHS list price of MST in the community segment
should be reduced by 20 per cent, with a floor price for MST sold in
hospitals of 25 per cent of the reduced community price. Following further
representations by Napp, the Directions, as finally made on 4 May 2001,
imposed a reduction of 15 per cent in the NHS price of MST, plus a floor
price for MST sold in hospitals of 20 per cent of that reduced community
price.
Factors affecting the amount of the penalty in the present
case
— Hospital pricing: seriousness
|
||
|
||
137 |
||
|
||
|
||
segment) that the predatory
pricing is designed to protect or strengthen. Unless predatory pricing,
and especially pricing below average variable cost, by dominant
undertakings is rigorously penalised by competition law, new competitive
entry may be thwarted, with the result that consumers never receive the
benefit of competitive conditions, and the lower long-run price levels,
wider choice and better quality which, in general, competition
brings.
|
||
|
||
138 |
||
|
||
|
||
affected by Napp’s conduct:
paragraphs 281 to 283 above. Nonetheless, we are prepared to make some
slight allowance, by way of mitigation, to take account of the fact that
OFT 414 is not drafted quite as clearly as it could have been, and the
fact that the Director’s case on follow-on effect and foreclosure has not
been expressed entirely consistently.
|
||
|
||
139 |
||
|
||
|
||
pricing policy about which Napp
chose, whether rightly or wrongly, to remain silent in the course of the
administrative procedure and the early stages of this appeal. We see no
mitigation there.
— Community pricing: seriousness
|
||
|
||
140 |
||
|
||
|
||
The Tribunal’s assessment of the
penalty
|
||
|
||
141 |
||
|
||
|
||
(the community segment). In
addition, Napp’s prices in the community segment have been maintained well
above the competitive level. If the objectives of the Act are to be
achieved such conduct calls, in our judgment, for severe penalties. In
those circumstances, absent any significant mitigating factors, we do not
think that a penalty of £3 million, as a global figure, is outside the
range of penalties that could reasonably be imposed, in a case such as the
present, having regard to the permitted maximum of £5.56
million.
Interest on the penalty
|
||
|
||
142 |
||
|
||
|
||
X — THE DIRECTIONS The
letter of 4 May 2001
“At paragraph 236 of the Decision
two elements of Napp’s conduct were found to infringe the Chapter II
prohibition. First, Napp was found to have charged excessive prices to
customers in the community segment of the market for the supply of
sustained release morphine tablets and capsules in the United Kingdom (the
relevant market). Second, Napp was found to have supplied sustained
release morphine tablets to the hospital segment of the relevant market at
discounts which have the object and effect of hindering competition in the
relevant market.
The Director considers that these
two elements of Napp’s pricing conduct are inter-related and must be
considered as a whole in formulating directions which are appropriate to
bring the infringement to an end. First, Napp’s ability to sustain high
prices in the community depends in large part on the effect of Napp’s
discounting behaviour to hospitals in hindering competition in the
relevant market. Second, the fact that Napp’s prices in the community
segment of the relevant market are significantly above those of its rivals
contributes to Napp’s asymetrical advantage in bidding for hospital
contracts.”
“The Director considers that an
immediate reduction in the NHS list price is appropriate in order to
mitigate Napp’s excessive prices in the community segment of the relevant
market in the short to medium term. This reduction, coupled with a
corresponding reduction in the ex-factory price of MST tablets sold to the
community, will also reduce Napp’s ability to cross-subsidise discounts in
the hospital segment of the relevant market. |
||
|
||
143 |
||
|
||
|
||
In the longer term, the Director
considers that the best way to prevent Napp from pricing excessively is to
maintain incentives, and to create opportunities, for competition to
develop throughout the relevant market.
The Director considers that the
appropriate level of reduction in the NHS list price would be fifteen per
cent. This will significantly reduce the price of MST tablets to the
community segment of the relevant market, while nevertheless allowing for
a gap between the price of MST tablets and that of Napp’s competitors,
thus maintaining incentives for competition to develop. This is consistent
with Napp’s representations that a reasonable price premium on MST tablets
should be allowed to reflect their current higher brand value relative to
that of rival products.”
“Paragraph 2(d) of the directions
provides that the price of each strength of MST tablet sold to hospitals
in the UK shall not be less than twenty per cent of the NHS list price for
that product strength of MST. The Director considers that this direction
is appropriate in order to prevent Napp from restricting competition by
supplying hospitals at excessively low prices.
The figure of twenty per cent
represents the ratio between Napp’s average cost of supplying MST tablets
to hospitals and the average NHS list price for those products arrived at
following the fifteen per cent reduction required by the direction at
paragraph 2(a). The calculation of Napp’s average cost of supplying MST
tablets to hospitals for this purpose is based on the total delivered cost
to Napp of supplying MST to hospitals in the UK over the period of March
to May 2000. The calculation of Napp’s average NHS list price, to which
the fifteen per cent reduction is then applied, is based on the volumes of
MST tablets supplied to hospitals in the UK over the same
period.
The direction at paragraph 2(d)
does not impose on Napp an absolute prohibition on supplying hospitals at
prices below the average cost. In order to do so, however, Napp would need
to reduce further its NHS list price for the product thus limiting its
ability to cross-subsidise discounts in the hospital segment and so, by
weakening the asymmetry between Napp’s position and that of its
competitors, increasing the opportunities for competition to
develop.
In its representations, Napp has
argued that in order to compete for hospital contracts it would have to
reduce the list price of MST tablets to unnecessarily low levels. First,
the Director does not consider that discounts to hospitals will remain at
their current level following implementation of the direction. Second, MST
tablets will maintain non-price advantages in competing for hospital
contracts owing to Napp’s position of dominance on the relevant
market.”
Arguments of the parties
144 |
||
|
||
|
||
II prohibition or the Act itself;
(iii) paragraph 6 of the Directions gives the Director power to obtain
information to which he is not entitled under the Act; (iv) paragraph 2(d)
of the Directions wrongly extends to private hospitals and hospices; (v)
there is no basis for requiring Napp to renegotiate its hospital contracts
in order to bring to an end any supposed infringement; (vi) there is no
basis for concluding that a reduction of at least 15 per cent in the
current NHS list price of MST is necessary in order to end Napp’s supposed
infringement; (vii) there is no basis for concluding that it is
appropriate to prohibit Napp from discounting its prices to hospitals to a
level which falls below 20 per cent of the NHS list price in order to end
Napp’s supposed infringement; (viii) by publishing the floor price in full
the Director is distorting competition, since its rivals will know at
precisely what level to undercut Napp, making up any losses from follow-on
linkages, while Napp is prevented from acting likewise.
|
||
|
||
145 |
||
|
||
|
||
Findings
146 |
||
|
||
|
||
or lessens the need for the
requirement to reduce by 15 per cent the list price of MST. That
requirement is necessary in order to remedy the distinct infringement of
excess pricing found in the Decision. As at the date of the Directions, 4
May 2001, Napp’s community prices were unfairly high, as we have
found.
|
||
|
||
147 |
||
|
||
|
||
XI — ORDERS MADE
|
||
|
||
148 |
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
|
||
Christopher Bellamy
Barry Colgate
Peter
Grinyer |
||
|
||
Delivered in open court
15 January
2002 |
||
|
||
Charles Dhanowa
Registrar |
||
|
||
149 |
||
|
||