BAILII is celebrating 24 years of free online access to the law! Would you consider making a contribution?
No donation is too small. If every visitor before 31 December gives just £1, it will have a significant impact on BAILII's ability to continue providing free access to the law.
Thank you very much for your support!
[Home] [Databases] [World Law] [Multidatabase Search] [Help] [Feedback] | ||
England and Wales High Court (Chancery Division) Decisions |
||
You are here: BAILII >> Databases >> England and Wales High Court (Chancery Division) Decisions >> Attheraces Ltd & Anor v British Horse Racing Board & Anor [2005] EWHC 3015 (Ch) (21 December 2005) URL: http://www.bailii.org/ew/cases/EWHC/Ch/2005/3015.html Cite as: [2005] EWHC 3015 (Ch) |
[New search] [Printable RTF version] [Help]
CHANCERY DIVISION
Strand, London, WC2A 2LL |
||
B e f o r e :
____________________
ATTHERACES Ltd & Anr |
Claimants |
|
- and - |
||
THE BRITISH HORSE RACING BOARD & Anr |
Defendants |
____________________
Michael Brindle Q.C, Maya Lester (instructed by Addeleshaw Goddard Solicitors) for the Defendants
Hearing dates: 20, 21, 24, 25, 26, 27, 31 October 2005
2, 3, 7, 8, 9 November 2005
____________________
Crown Copyright ©
Introduction | 1-13 |
Summary of analysis and conclusions | 14 |
British racing | 15-34 |
The principal authorities | 15-25 |
BHB's Database and industry modernisation | 26-34 |
Contractual arrangements ATR/BHB up to 29 March 2004 | 35-45 |
Contractual arrangements ATR/BHB after 29 March 2004 | 46-58 |
Involvement of the OFT and the CAT | 59-65 |
Communications and negotiations between ATR and BHB leading to these proceedings | 66-96 |
Developments in the proceedings prior to trial | 96-111 |
Witnesses | 111-119 |
Witnesses of fact | 111-117 |
Expert evidence | 118-119 |
Article 82 of the EC Treaty | 120 |
The Competition Act 1998 s.18 | 121-123 |
Burden of proof | 123-128 |
Dominant position | 129-133 |
The market | 134-231 |
The product market | 135-136 |
The product | 137-166 |
The relevant product market | 166-173 |
The SSNIP test and the competitive price | 174-213 |
The constraints of the downstream market | 214-228 |
Conclusion on the SSNIP test | 229-231 |
Geographical extent of the market | 232-233 |
Dominance | 234-239 |
Unreasonable refusal to supply data | 240-284 |
Excessive pricing | 285-308 |
Discriminatory pricing | 309-328 |
The Government's proposals | 329-331 |
Decision | 332-333 |
Annexes | Annexes |
Mr Justice Etherton :
Introduction
Summary of analysis and conclusions
i) The product supplied by BHB is UK pre-race data. It is not, as contended by BHB "the ability to create value from the whole show of British racing". It is not a bundle comprising both British pre-race data and British racing pictures.ii) The relevant product market is, as contended by ATR, the market for the supply of UK pre-race data to those in the horse racing industry that require such information for the services they provide their customers (in particular bookmakers and producers of TV channels or internet sites relating to horse racing). That conclusion is confirmed by the application of the economist's SSNIP test.
iii) The geographical extent of that product market, for the purposes of these proceedings, is all countries outside the UK and Ireland; but it makes no difference to the outcome of the case if that is incorrect and the geographical extent of the market is the world.
iv) BHB is dominant in that market.
v) BHB has abused its market dominance by threatening to terminate the supply of pre-race data to ATR, even though ATR is an existing customer of BHB and pre-race data is an essential facility controlled by BHB, without which ATR would be eliminated from the market. There is no objective justification for such conduct of BHB. It is irrelevant that BHB and ATR are not competitors. BHB seeks to justify its proposals as to price, which ATR refused to accept, as being reasonable charges on ATR's overseas customers- who would otherwise be "free riders" – collected through the agency of ATR, but that is not a correct description of them as a matter of substance or form: they would be charges on ATR in substance and form. Further the prices proposed prior to the commencement of the proceedings were unfairly excessive, and also discriminated unfairly against ATR. Further, BHB continued to insist, until after the commencement of the proceedings, that ATR enter into an intellectual property licence from BHB, even though the use by ATR of BHB's pre-race data would not infringe any intellectual property right of BHB.
vi) The prices specified from time to time by BHB to ATR prior to the commencement of the proceedings were excessive and unfair, and so an abuse of BHB's dominant position in the market, because they were significantly in excess of the economic value of BHB's pre-race data and not otherwise justified. The economic value of the data is to be measured, on the facts of the case, by the cost to BHB of producing its Database (about £5m) together with a reasonable return on that cost. BHB's proposed charges to ATR were so far in excess of any justifiable allocation to ATR of that amount as to be plainly excessive. I reject BHB's contention that its proposed prices are justified by the right or need to take into account the cost of the positive "externality" of British racing, that is to say the cost of providing those aspects of British racing which make it an attractive subject matter for broadcast and for betting. BHB's proposed prices were not justified by any application of the economic principle of Ramsay pricing.
vii) The prices specified from time to time by BHB to ATR prior to the commencement of the proceedings were an abuse of BHB's market dominance because they were substantially in excess of BHB's normal charge for broadcasters, and also because they differed from, and would have had more onerous consequences than, BHB's pricing mechanism for ATR's direct competitor Phumelela Gold Enterprises ("Phumelela"), in both cases for no justifiable reason and so unfairly discriminating against ATR.
viii) In the absence of any public interest defence under Article 86 of the EC Treaty ("Article 86") or para. 4 of Schedule 3 to the 1998 Act, the fact that a decision against BHB in the present case would have serious consequences for the proposals and plans of the Government and BHB to modernise British racing by "commercialising" BHB's assets and replacing the statutory Levy on bookmakers cannot affect the outcome of the proceedings. Nor can it make any difference to a proper application of Article 82 and s. 18 of the 1998 Act that BHB has been motivated, in its proposals to ATR, by the wider interests of British racing rather than private profit.
British racing
The principal authorities
BHB's Database and industry modernisation
Contractual arrangements ATR/BHB up to 29 March 2004
Contractual arrangements ATR/BHB after 29 March 2004
Involvement of the OFT and the CAT
Communications and negotiations between ATR and BHB leading to these proceedings
"If ATR is not prepared to do this, and to make these payments to BHB, or arrange for such payments to be made to BHB, we reserve the right to be exercised on 3 days written notice from us, to require you not to use our data in your services, and will take all necessary legal steps we consider appropriate to enforce our rights in this regard."
"...in respect of your failure to offer a data licence agreement on reasonable terms or at all to our clients to use race and runner data ("the Data") in relation to British horse racing. Please note, for the purposes of this letter, we do not raise any issue in relation to whether any rights in fact subsist within the Data. However pending final determination by the European Court of Justice in C-203/02 British Horse Racing Board Ltd and others v William Hill Organisation Ltd our client reserves its rights in this regard."
"Your client has been informed that it will receive a data licence to be able to broadcast live racing to domestic customers via satellite and cable. The issue of this licence is not dependent on the payment of monies already owed by ATR. The licence is in draft form and will be issued to your clients shortly. In the meantime until that licence is concluded, we confirm that ATR may use BHB's data solely for the purpose of the broadcasting of racing for which it has picture rights to domestic customers in Great Britain via satellite or cable television and for static displays of information on its web-site."
A copy of a proposed IP data licence for the ATR Channel in the UK was in
due course supplied to ATR by BHB's solicitors on 4 August 2004.
"I note your offer to pay 50% of net revenues from SIS in relation to international distribution as an interim arrangement for the period post 29 March, subject to confirmation that the courses not aligned to ATR which had licensed distribution rights to SIS during the same period were also being charged 50% of net revenue for data. I can confirm that BHB has and will charge not less than 50% of net revenues for data from whatever source".
"From our reading of that judgment it now appears that BHB has no right to impose terms upon ATR for its use of such information. Our previous discussions have been premised upon what has proven to be a mistaken understanding of the law applicable to the BHB's rights, the legal position having now been clarified by the ECJ… we invite you to set out in full what the BHB's position is concerning ATR's use of the information in the light of the ECJ judgment".
"Your letter does not provide any details of how copyright subsists in BHB's database and, if it does subsist, how ATR may have infringed that copyright, which allegation, if made, is denied. I believe it would be helpful if you set out the BHB's position in writing before any meeting between us. In the meantime, I will have to reserve ATR's position with regard to any such claim in copyright."
"Unless it is agreed that £900 per fixture is paid on behalf of end users outside the UK and Ireland, for pre-race data provided with pictures relating to racecourses covered by [ATR] BHB has taken the decision that it will instruct SIS that it may no longer broadcast pre race data to bookmakers which do not have a BHB data licence, which for all practical purposes is SIS' customer base. BHB is prepared, if SIS so wish it, to enter into an agreement with ATR in place of SIS. This would be a short term contract with a six month notice period, which will then allow more time to enter into negotiations for a longer term agreement. The agreement would extend to land based bookmakers only and would therefore not cover internet bookmakers who would continue to be required by BHB to enter into direct data licences.
The agreement will be retroactive and cover all 2004 races for which payment has not already been made by SIS. I will send you a note of the liability under separate cover, for which BHB will also require payment by ATR under this proposal."
"...that you have written to me in the terms of your letter, most particularly in the context of my letter of 3rd December 2004 remaining unanswered. You have not been able to explain what protectable rights the BHB is entitled to enforce."
The letter continued:
"Finally, I am sure that you do not need to be reminded that a contract is in place between ATR and SIS which would be adversely affected by any attempts by the BHB to persuade, induce or procure SIS not to broadcast pre-race data which affects ATR's business in any way (or indeed succeeds in doing so). Nevertheless, if the BHB does take such steps, then ATR will take such action as is available to it (including legal proceedings) to protect its position."
"...I have no real concern over the contract in place between you and SIS, and how that might be affected by BHB's position. The position is very straightforward. SIS, under its existing contractual arrangements with BHB, is only permitted to make use of the data taken from BHB's database and deliver it to third parties, if those third parties have concluded a data licence with BHB. In the absence of the conclusion of such data licences, BHB has the contractual right, as you are aware, and which has been in place from well before your contract with SIS, to require SIS to cease supplying those unauthorised end users. Whilst BHB receives the relevant payments for use of its data within the services provided by SIS, it can be prepared to consider forgoing the need for there to be a data licence in place with the relevant end users. However in the absence of such payment, or other contractual arrangements protecting BHB's rights, BHB has no alternative but to enforce its rights, and require SIS not to supply data to third parties who do not have such a concluded data licence in place.
BHB has similar agreements in place, most notably with PA. PA is not permitted to supply unauthorised users with BHB's data. If no licence(s) are in place with ATR, BHB is entitled to require its authorised suppliers not to supply data to ATR....
In the light of this I invite you to revisit the proposal in my 10 February letter."
"confirmed that BHB does have a database right in the racing information database… and extends to overseas users which BHB has to date regarded as authorised on the basis that fees were being paid by intermediaries on their behalf."
The writer then gave notice that "unless ATR enters into a licence agreement with BHB within 14 days BHB will instruct its authorised suppliers to withdraw supply of BHB's data to ATR".
Developments in the proceedings prior to the trial
"BHB's requirement is either that ATR only supplies data to bookmakers who have a direct agreement with BHBE [the Second Claimant] or itself agrees with BHBE to collect from each bookmaker and pay to BHBE a fee amounting to 1.5% of turnover or 10% of gross profit derived from that bookmaker's British horse race betting business or, alternatively, to pay to BHBE a collective sum of £1,800.00 for each fixture in respect of which data is supplied. In addition, it would be required to pay 10% of the profit it receives from the bookmaker for that service."
Witnesses
Witnesses of fact
Expert evidence
Article 82 of the EC Treaty
"Any abuse by one or more undertakings of a dominant position within the common market or in a substantial part of it shall be prohibited as incompatible with the common market in so far as it may affect trade between Member States.
Such abuse may, in particular, consist in:
(a) directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair trading conditions;
(b) limiting production, markets or technical development to the prejudice of consumers;
(c) applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties, thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage;
(d) making the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by the other parties of supplementary obligations which, by their nature or according to commercial usage, have no connection with the subject of such contracts.
The Competition Act 1998 s.18
"18 Abuse of dominant position
1) Subject to section 19, any conduct on the part of one or more undertakings which amounts to the abuse of a dominant position in a market is prohibited if it may affect trade within the United Kingdom.
(2) Conduct may, in particular, constitute such an abuse if it consists in-
(a) directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair trading conditions;
(b) limiting production, markets or technical development to the prejudice of consumers;
(c) applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties, thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage;
(d) making the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by the other parties of supplementary obligations which, by their nature or according to commercial usage, have no connection with the subject of the contracts.
(3) In this section-
"dominant position" means a dominant position within the United Kingdom; and
"the United Kingdom" means the United Kingdom or any part of it.
(4) The prohibition imposed by subsection (1) is referred to in this Act as "the Chapter II prohibition".
Burden of proof
Dominant position
"…a position of economic strength enjoyed by an undertaking which enables it to prevent effective competition being maintained on the relevant market by affording it the power to behave to an appreciable extent independently of its competitors, customers and ultimately of consumers":
Case 27/76 United Brands Company and United Brands Continentaal BV v Commission [1978] ECR 207: Case 85/76 Hoffman-La Roche v Commission [1979] ECR 461 at para 38; Case T-228/97 Irish Sugar v Commission [1999] ECR II – 2969 at para 7.
"such a position does not preclude some competition … but enables the undertaking which profits from it, if not to determine, at least to have an appreciable influence on the conditions under which competition will develop, and in any case to act largely in disregard of it so long as such conduct does not act to its detriment."
"(i) market definition: defining the relevant product market and the relevant geographic market (which must comprise at least a substantial part of the common market) in which the market power of the allegedly dominant undertaking is to be assessed;
(ii) market share analysis: establishing the market share of the undertaking in question on the relevant market so defined;
(iii) analysis of competitive constraints: assessing the significance attributable to the market share of the undertaking in question and in particular whether it is likely to be eroded by actual or potential competitors."
The market
The product market
"2.5 The process of defining a market typically begins by establishing the closest substitutes to the product (or group of products) that is the focus of the investigation. These substitute products are the most immediate competitive constraints on the behaviour of the undertaking supplying the product in question. In order to establish which products are 'close enough' substitutes to be in the relevant market, a conceptual framework known as the hypothetical monopolist test (the test) is usually employed.
…
2.7 In essence the test seeks to establish the smallest product group (and geographical area) such that a hypothetical monopolist controlling that product group (in that area) could profitably sustain 'supra competitive' prices, i.e. prices that are at least a small but significant amount above competitive levels. That product group (and area) is usually the relevant market.
2.8 If, for example, a hypothetical monopolist over a candidate product group could not profitably sustain supra competitive prices, then the candidate product group would be too narrow to be a relevant market. If, on the other hand, a hypothetical monopolist over a subset of a candidate product group could profitably sustain supra competitive prices, then the relevant market would usually be narrower than the candidate product group.
2.9 The steps in applying this approach are as follows. We start by considering a hypothetical monopolist of the focal product (i.e. the product under investigation) which operates in a focal area (i.e. an area under investigation in which the focal product is sold).
2.10 We then ask whether it would be profitable for the hypothetical monopolist to sustain the price of the focal product a small but significant amount (e.g. 5 to 10 per cent) above competitive levels. If the answer to this question is 'yes', the test is complete. The product and area under the hypothetical monopolist's control is (usually) the relevant market.
2.11 If the answer to this question is 'no', this is typically because a sufficiently large number of customers would switch some of their purchases to other substitute products (or areas). In this case, we assume further that the hypothetical monopolist controls both the focal product and its closest substitute. We then repeat the process, but this time in relation to the larger set of products (or areas) under the hypothetical monopolist's control.
2.12 As before, we ask whether it would be profitable to sustain prices 5 to 10 per cent above competitive levels. If so, the test is complete. The relevant market is (usually) the focal product and its closest substitute. If not, we assume that the hypothetical monopolist also controls the second closest substitute to the focal product and repeat the process once more. We continue expanding the product group in this way (i.e. by adding the next best substitute) until we have found a group of products (or areas) for which it is profitable for the hypothetical monopolist to sustain prices 5 to 10 per cent above competitive levels (by adding the next best substitute)."
The product
"9.10 …what is being purchased is the ability to create value from British racing…"
"10.1 … the relevant product that ATR consumes in this case is the ability to create value from the whole show of British racing, separate and distinct from the mechanism by which that can be obtained, or more correctly, legitimately withheld. That mechanism is the pre-race data sourced from the BHB Database, whether by direct access to the BHB Database or delivery via PA in this case."
"10.6…Thus, in providing a high value whole show, BHB (and to an extent the Jockey Club) have to perform a governance role that ensures integrity, meritocracy, competitive balance, and solidarity and fixture co-ordination between courses, whilst ensuring that the conflicting needs of the different consumers and users (TV, bookmakers, owners, racegoers etc) are met and balanced."
"10.7… It is the whole show that generates value for users and it is access to this whole show that users are buying and selling to others. It is the aggregate activities of the BHB and Jockey Club that generate the (value of) the whole show."
"12.2…The first step, the definition of the relevant product (what the OFT call the focal product), seeks to identify what customers actually consume. The Claimants see the relevant product as Pre Race Data. However what they are actually consuming is a relevant product defined more widely, since the data allows them the opportunity to create value from British racing (whole show). For convenience the relevant product is hereafter called British racing."
"14.16…Thus the relevant product should more correctly be seen as the opportunity to create value from the British racing whole show."
"BHB's primary case is that it is a crucial first step in the analysis to realise that the product being consumed is not just any old data ("low-grade" data as ATR put it in opening…) but is British racing data, with all the costs, value, quality and attributes associated with that product. That product includes both British racing data and British racing pictures. It is that product as a whole that allows bookmakers (UK and overseas) to accept bets on British racing. Accordingly, it is that product which creates the positive externality for which payment must be made via BHB's data charge."
"any increase in the amount a licensee has to pay for the Non-LBO rights is likely to be matched by a decrease in the amount it is willing to pay for the data rights…ATR stipulated that the courses and/or RCA would ensure that the BHB data rights were made available to ATR "free of charge"".
"The economist witnesses called on behalf of the respondents took a different view. Although each of them expressed himself in his own way we think it is fair to say that, on what may be called the cartel argument, they all took a line which accords with the following passage in the first report of Professor Yamey, who was called on behalf of the Premier League:
2.2 …In several important respects the collective licensing arrangements, viewed as a set of economic/commercial arrangements, are quite different from the ordinary business cartel.
2.3 In a widgets cartel, the cartel itself produces no output that is distinct from and additional to the outputs of the cartel members. Competition between widget manufacturers is desirable because it benefits the public as consumers by generating better and cheaper products. By contrast the FAPL [Football Association Premier League Ltd] produces a product, the PL [Premier League] competition, i.e. the PL championship, which no single PL club can produce, nor even any sub-set of PL clubs. It is a product that is jointly, i.e. collectively, produced by the PL clubs. Even the least successful of the least popular clubs contribute to the PL collective product. Each club has an interest in the PL competition no greater nor less than any other. The bottom clubs can and do spring surprises playing against the top ones. Each club plays an integral part in all aspects of the competition no greater nor less than any other. The bottom clubs can and do spring surprises playing against the top ones. Each club plays an integral part in all aspects of the competition, in determining the championship, those who qualify for European competition and those to be relegated.
2.4 Moreover the derived products stemming from the PL competition, the individual PL matches, are such that no single PL club can produce a unit of output: it takes two clubs to produce a match. It takes only one widget manufacturing firm to produce a widget.
2.5 The PL competition consists of a series of inter-connected matches extending over a season. In a given season the public's interest in a particular PL match depends in part on the outcomes of all the preceding PL matches and on the state of the PL league table.
2.6 More generally, the value of the television rights in any particular match is affected by the value of the PL product itself, i.e. the PL competition, and the public's interest and enthusiasm it succeeds in generating. Other things being equal, the less interest the PL competition is generating, the less valuable are the television rights in any one PL match. This consideration applies to the broadcasting of live matches and also of highlight programmes. "
The relevant product market
"The concept of the relevant market in fact implies that there can be effective competition between the products which form part of it and this presupposes that there is a sufficient degree of interchangeability between all the products forming part of the same market in so far as a specific use of such products is concerned."
"According to settled case-law, for the purposes of applying Article [82] of the Treaty, the relevant product or service market includes products or services which are substitutable or sufficiently interchangeable with the product or service in question, not only in terms of their objective characteristics, by virtue of which they are particularly suitable for satisfying the constant needs of consumers, but also in terms of the conditions of competition and/or the structure of supply and demand on the market in question (Case 31/80 L'Oreal [1980] ECR 3775, paragraph 25; Case 322/81 Michelin v Commission [1983] ECR 3461, paragraph 37; Case C-62/86 AKZO Chemie v Commission[1991] ECR I-3359, paragraph 51; Case T-30/89 Hilti v Commission [1991] ECR II-1439, paragraph 64, and Case T-83/91 Tetra Pak v Commission [1994] ECR II-755, paragraph 63)."
"96. The foregoing cases indicate that the relevant product market is to be defined by reference to the facts in any given case, taking into account the whole economic context, which may include notably (i) the objective characteristics of the products; (ii) the degree of substitutability or interchangeability between the products, having regard to their relative prices and intended use; (iii) the competitive conditions; (iv) the structure of the supply and demand; and (v) the attitudes of consumers and users.
97. However, this check list is neither fixed, nor exhaustive, nor is every element mentioned in the case law necessarily mandatory in every case. Each case will depend on its own facts, and it is necessary to examine the particular circumstances in order to answer what, at the end of the day, are relatively straightforward questions: do the products concerned sufficiently compete with each other to be sensibly regarded as being in the same market? Are there other products which should be regarded as competing in the same market? The key idea is that of a competitive constraint: do the other products alleged to form part of the same market act as a competitive constraint on the conduct of the allegedly dominant firm?"
The SSNIP test and the competitive price
"A reasonable price to ATR for the use of the BHB database would raise only as much revenue as is required to fund ATR's appropriate share of the total revenue requirement that is needed to keep the database operating. I approach this problem below by sharing the estimated BHB revenue requirement proportionally to the turnover of various users on services that depend on BHB database. Consistently with this approach, the costs of upkeep of the database and the associated investments can be shared as follow….
Table 2
Turnover generated on British horse races and database cost split by user, year 2005 (£'000)
Turnover | % of Total Turnover | Contribution to database | |
Database cost (Weatherbys) | 5,248 | ||
Contribution from: | |||
UK bookmakers | 6,533,333 | 89.81% | 4,713.3 |
Irish bookmakers | 593,393 | 8.16% | 428.1 |
South African bookmakers | 43,103 | 0.59% | 57.5 |
Italian bookmakers | 19,909 | 0.27% | 31.1 |
ATR International | 2,279 | 0.03% | 1.6 |
SIS Facts | 2,767 | 0.04% | 2.0 |
According to the estimates provided in Table 2, the price that ATR should pay for using BHB's database "utility" is approximately £1,600 per year, plus an appropriate share of the £119,700 due from bookmakers in Italy, South Africa, and other countries. (This can be compared to the £52,000 per annum paid by ATR to PA for the supply of the data). The great majority of the database revenue should come from the UK bookmakers whose betting turnover on British horse racing naturally greatly exceeds that from overseas bookmakers."
"5.1 …Economic relationships have… effects that go beyond trading or other relationships and affect third parties or "bystanders". These effects are called externalities because one entity directly affects the welfare of another that is external to it. In such circumstances, externalities typically have an adverse effect on economic efficiency. This adverse effect can arise whether the influence of the externality is positive or negative. For example, if the externality is beneficial to another entity (a positive externality), too little will be produced and, similarly, if the externality has a harmful (negative) effect, then too much is produced. In that respect an externality does not differ from a normal good or service within a competitive market economy. The efficient price of such a good or service in the market will ensure that the optimal amount is produced and consumed.
5.2 The adverse effect on efficiency comes about when providers of the service do not internalise external costs or benefits when making production decisions…"
He goes on to say:
"9.2 The benefit that is provided to bookmakers by high quality racing is significant… Absent the Levy, this would be a free positive externality for bookmakers and punters, obtained as a by-product of British Racing. Absent a market and correspondingly a price being placed on the value of British racing to bookmakers and other users, it is not possible for racing to supply or users to demand what they want. In economic terms, the Levy is an attempt to create such a market by administrative means.
9.3 Accordingly, the purpose of the Levy and of any subsequent commercial mechanism is broadly a payment by bookmakers for the ability to create value from British racing. The funds, so raised, are required to improve the quality and integrity of racing and the breed…
9.4 The aims of the BHB and the Horserace Betting Levy Board (HBLB) are very broadly similar.
9.5 The Levy, created as it was in the early 1960's, applied to LBO bookmakers and did not foresee subsequent technological developments in media and betting opportunities for creating value from British racing. Nevertheless, the principle underlying the Levy (a payment for the externality) applies equally to all the additional ways that users now create value from British racing.
9.6 The commercial mechanism which has been developed at the instigation of the Government to replace the Levy has a wider scope than the Levy. It is designed to ensure payment for the positive benefits (externalities) provided by racing to third parties generally, for example the media, and not just for the benefits provided by racing to LBO bookmakers. The commercial mechanism has a further advantage over the Levy. As it is a freely negotiated market price it will (providing that the externalities can be priced as a consequence of the ability to exclude those who seek to create value from British racing) give rise to a preferable outcome for all users compared to the administratively set price of the Levy.
9.7 The commercial mechanism is in effect the means by which the positive externalities conferred upon third parties are priced efficiently. It is irrelevant whether those third parties were or were not covered by the Levy or whether they are defined as a bookmaker or not. Those who benefit from British racing should pay for that ability to create value from British racing.
9.8 It is important to recognise that what is being provided to ATR and others is the ability to create value from British racing. Control of access to the BHB Database is the mechanism by which BHB is able to withhold the ability to create value. The essence of any efficient transaction on price is that the seller can refuse to sell and the buyer can refuse to buy. As explained earlier, BHB's coordinating role and its broad representative structure enables that transaction to take place efficiently."
"6. As a matter of welfare economics it is generally desirable that an externality is priced. Externalities can be priced (i.e. internalised) by regulation/tax or by voluntary negotiation between the parties affected."
"9. All things being equal, the greater is the size of the externality, the greater are the economic benefits for society of pricing or otherwise internalising the externality."
"1 0. A financial contribution to the racing industry by bookmakers and other "users" of racing can provide a mechanism by which beneficiaries can influence the quantity and quality of racing."
"British horse racing faces significant challenges from uncertainty over its future funding; and increased competition from other leisure pursuits… The Levy Board system has contributed to a lack of commercial funding, by preventing British horse racing from fully exploiting its product on a proper commercial basis. Only a relatively limited amount of revenue is presently raised from the exploitation of media rights…it is clear that the Government wishes to see British racing operating, like other sports, on a fully commercial basis without state intervention…The future of British horse racing therefore depends on its public profile being raised. Racing must become an attractive, broad-based leisure activity, generating a dependable and long-term income stream, the principal source of which must inevitably be the betting industry…
The Notified Arrangement [ATR1]… will play a critical role in securing the financial future of British racing as it moves into a new commercial environment…as the industry moves away from current Levy funding arrangements. The increased revenue will enable the industry to invest in new facilities at racecourses and to raise prize money, which will help to retain existing owners as participants in British racing and to attract new owners to the sport, as well as increasing activity and employment in related areas such as training, and bloodstock sales… The Notified Arrangement will help racing to compete more effectively with other leisure interests for the 'leisure pound', and therefore provides the basis for considerable improvements to the British racing industry…
"The Notified Arrangement is the most efficient and effective means of delivering the benefits, both to consumers and to British horse racing… [and] does not result in the appreciable prevention, restriction, or distortion of competition in any relevant market
"The sale of the Rights pursuant to the Rights Agreement will enable the Courses to develop new facilities for participants, spectators and on-course bookmakers and ensure the continuation of racing at a local level: see the BHB Future Funding Plan …
Increased income will enable increased prize-money, which will make British racing more competitive internationally, helping it to develop further and thereby promote economic progress…. Increasing prize money would improve the international competitiveness and quality of British racing through increasing field sizes and horse population…British racing will also benefit from increased overseas interest in British racing, for example, from sharing in any revenues that Attheraces may earn from broadcasting British racing in other countries (or from licensing others to do this) and from international betting, for example through the Attheraces website: there is already considerable interest in British racing overseas, for example in America and the far East which is regarded as having integrity and reliability, thereby making it an attractive subject for gambling.
Racehorse owners, trainers, breeders, jockeys, sponsors and other participants in the British racing industry will benefit from the greater sums of money that will flow into the sport and from the greater public profile that the sport will enjoy as a result of Attheraces' exploitation of the Rights and its marketing of British racing. These benefits will be shared by consumers through the resulting improved quality of British racing".
" … prices and profits may be high in markets where there is innovation. Successful innovation may allow a firm to earn profits significantly higher than those of its competitors. However, a high return in one period could provide a fair return on the investment in an earlier period required to bring about the innovation. These costs include investment in research and development and should take into account the risk at the time of the investment that the innovation might have failed."
"2. Undertakings entrusted with the operation of services of general economic interest or having the character of a revenue-producing monopoly shall be subject to the rules contained in this Treaty, in particular to the rules on competition, in so far as the application of such rules does not obstruct the performance, in law or in fact, of the particular tasks assigned to them. The development of trade must not be affected to such an extent as would be contrary to the interests of the Community."
"Neither the Chapter I prohibition nor the Chapter II prohibition applies to an undertaking entrusted with the operation of services of general economic interest or having the character of a revenue-producing monopoly in so far as the prohibition would obstruct the performance, in law or in fact, of the particular tasks assigned to that undertaking."
The constraints of the downstream market
"When considering the substitutes of a wholesale product, it may be necessary to consider substitution possibilities at the downstream level. For example, suppose a supplier produces a wholesale product A which is a necessary input for supply of a retail product B. Suppose also that a vertically integrated supplier that does not supply a substitute wholesale product supplies a product C which is a substitute for B at the retail level. The ability of customers to substitute to product C from product B at the retail level may constrain the ability to raise the price of the wholesale product A."
"Horse racing is, at the very least, substitutable with a wide range of other sports... This indicates that many other sports rights should be considered within the same relevant market as that in which the sale and purchase of the Rights takes place. In terms of the 'hypothetical monopolist test', the price that the Courses may charge for the Rights is constrained to the competitive level, in the first instance, by the availability of rights to broadcast a wide range of other sports. Moreover, the ultimate objective of the purchasers of such rights is to produce programming that interests and entertains viewers…. From a demand side perspective, these types of rights are clearly substitutable….
The Applicants also consider that the amount that the Courses may charge for the Rights is constrained by the ability of potential purchasers of the Rights to purchase rights to a wide variety of other types of video programming rights, including, for example, movies, game shows, and other light / general entertainment programming… The geographic scope of the market for the supply of rights to video programming is national, or at most the UK and Ireland. Programming rights are, in general, defined on a territory-by-territory basis by rights owners as a result of linguistic, regulatory and economic factors"
Conclusion on the SSNIP test
Geographical extent of the market
"The geographic scope of the relevant market is best considered to be world-wide, although the commercial behaviour of the BHB has effectively segmented the market in three regions: the UK, the Republic of Ireland, and overseas countries."
Dominance
Unreasonable refusal to supply data
"A dominant company therefore has a special obligation not to do anything that would cause further deterioration to the already fragile structure of competition or to unfairly prevent the emergence or growth of new or existing competitors who might challenge this dominance and bring about the establishment of effective competition".
"a special responsibility not to allow its conduct to impair genuine undistorted competition": cp Michelin at para 57.
"It is well established that such a special responsibility may deprive a dominant undertaking of the right to adopt a course of conduct that would be unobjectionable if adopted by a non-dominant undertaking (Case T-111/96 ITT Promedia v Commission [1998] ECR II-2937, paragraph 139), but the actual scope of that special responsibility must be considered in the light of the specific circumstances of each case: Compagnie Maritime Belge [2000] ECR I-1365 at paragraph 114. We for our part accept and follow the opinion of Mr Advocate General Fennelly in Compagnie Maritime Belge, cited above, that the special responsibility of a dominant undertaking is particularly onerous where it is a case of quasi-monopolist enjoying "dominance approaching monopoly", "superdominance" or "overwhelming dominance verging on monopoly" [2000] ECR I-1365 at paras 132 and 137"
BHB enjoyed and enjoys such standing in the supply of UK pre-race data.
"Undertakings that are not dominant are generally free to choose for themselves the parties with whom they wish to enter into contractual relations. In the case of dominant undertakings, however, that freedom may be curtailed and a refusal to deal may constitute an abuse of dominance. An offer to supply only on terms that the supplier knows to be unacceptable will be a constructive refusal to supply. The precise boundaries of the circumstances in which a dominant undertaking's refusal to deal may constitute an abuse remain to be determined. However, it is clear that, in the absence of objective justification, a refusal to supply an existing customer will be an abuse, as will a refusal to grant access to essential facilities;"
And see United Brands at paras 182-183; Case C-7/97 Oscar Bronner GmbH and Co KG v Mediaprint Zeitungs und Zeitschriftenverlag GmbH & Co KG [1998] ECR I-1365 at paras 35-43 (AG Jacobs)
"..a competitor is unable practically or reasonably to duplicate the essential facility. It is not sufficient that duplication would be difficult or expensive, but absolute impossibility is not required."
"…intervention of that kind, whether understood as an application of the essential facilities doctrine or, more traditionally, as a response to a refusal to supply goods or services, can be justified in terms of competition policy only in cases in which the dominant undertaking has a genuine stranglehold on the related market. That might be the case for example where duplication of the facility is impossible or extremely difficult owing to physical, geographic or legal constraints or is highly undesirable for reasons of public policy."…( my emphasis)"
See also para 41 of the ECJ's judgment ("…no actual or potential substitute in existence…").
i) "The BHB Database is the only place from which the BHB pre-race data emanates for all of the 59 racecourses in Great Britain. If ATR cannot obtain this information, directly or indirectly from the BHB then there is nowhere else to obtain the information (at least in a reliable and up to date form)." (Mr Imi's 1st witness statement at para 36)ii) "BHB is in practice the only supplier of key data required by ATR to provide the services it offers". (Mr Imi's 3rd witness statement at para 74:)
iii) "the commodity which enables bookmakers to generate income from British racing is data, specifically each day's daily feed of pre-race data…Without access to this information on a day to day basis, and without the accuracy of such data being guaranteed, bookmakers could not operate their bookmaking business in relation to British racing." (Mr Nichols' 3rd witness statement at para 12.1)
iv) "…data is the key which enables consumers to generate revenue from racing." (Mr Nichols' 3rd witness statement at para 19.4:)
v) The OFT said in its Rule 14 Notice:
"Currently, British racecourses cannot independently exploit the basic, but commercially most important, information relating to their activities, namely race and runners data. This is the essential data concerning an individual race and the horses running in it that a bookmaker needs to take bets on a race. This is a key asset, as all bookmakers need this data. This data is currently only available from the BHB. While a bookmaker may buy live coverage rights direct from racecourses, it must go to the BHB for the corresponding data. Racecourses are therefore dependent on the BHB for the largest part of their income. There is an effective monopoly in the supply of this data, a position that the OFT considers is created and maintained by the operation of the Orders and Rules."vi) BHB said in its response to the OFT that it was the only source of the data relating to horses taking part in horse races and that "there are no other sources of the data, which belongs to the BHB".
vii) BHB in its board meeting in January 1999 considered that it would not be appropriate to undertake a "quantum leap" in income from pre-race information as this might be considered to be an abuse by BHB of its "monopoly"
Excessive pricing
"Although the price level of the product does not necessarily suffice to disclose the abuse of a dominant position within the meaning of Article 86, it may, however, if unjustified by any objective criteria, and if it is particularly high be a determining factor." (judgment of 18 December 1970, Case 40/70, Sirena S.r.l. v Eda S.r.l. and Others [1971] ECR 70) quoted in the Opinion of AG Mayras in United Brands at p.338.)
"2.1 The charging of excessive selling prices…by a dominant undertaking may be an infringement of the Chapter II prohibition.
…
2.3 An important area where excessive prices might be viewed as an abuse is where a dominant undertaking is exploiting its ownership of an essential facility, an important network facility which is unlikely to face competition in the foreseeable future. In addition to having no relation to the economic value of the product supplied, such excessive prices might make it more difficult for undertakings (that require the product as an input) to enter and compete in related markets.
…
2.6 An undertaking's prices in a particular market can be regarded as excessive if they allow the undertaking to sustain profits higher than it could expect to earn in a competitive market (in this guideline called supra-normal profits). …
…
2.14 As explained above, supra-normal profits are profits earned in a particular market which are sustained at a level in excess of the risk-adjusted cost of capital for investment in the business serving that market."
"390. In paragraph 203 of the Decision, the Director states that, as a matter of principle a price is excessive for the purposes of the Chapter II prohibition:
"if it is above that which would exist in a competitive market and where it is clear that high profits will not stimulate successful new entry within a reasonable period. Therefore, to show that prices are excessive, it must be demonstrated that (i) prices are higher than would be expected in a competitive market, and (ii) there is no effective competitive pressure to bring them down to competitive levels, nor is there likely to be"
391. While there may well be other ways of approaching the issue of unfair prices under section 18(2)(A) of the Act, the Director's starting point, as stated in paragraph 203 of the Decision, seems to us to be soundly based in the circumstances of the present case.
392. Measuring whether a price is above the level that would exist in a competitive market is rarely an easy task. The fact that the exercise may be difficult is not, however, a reason for not attempting it. In the present case, the methods used by the Director are various comparisons of (i) Napp's prices with Napp's costs, (ii) Napp's prices with the costs of its next most profitable competitor, (iii) Napp's prices with those of its competitors and (iv) Napp's prices with prices charged by Napp in other markets. Those methods seem to us to be among the approaches that may reasonably be used to establish excessive prices, although there are, no doubt, other methods.
…
400. It is therefore established, on the facts of this case, that during the period of infringement Napp charged significantly higher prices in the community segment than in other markets or segments where it faced competition, and has significantly higher margins in the community segment than its most profitable competitor. In addition, Napp faced no competitive pressure on its prices in the community segment, had no patent protection, and enjoyed a market share of 96 percent throughout.
401. The fact that the Director has not chosen to rely on other comparators such as international price comparisons or returns on capital does not in our view lessen the force of the comparators upon which he does rely. Napp itself has not, in the notice of appeal, put forward any other comparators.
402. On those facts we are satisfied that Napp "has made use of the opportunities arising out of its dominant position in such a way as to reap trading benefits which it would not have reaped if there had been normal and sufficiently effective competition", so as to satisfy the test of abuse as laid down by he Court of Justice in United Brands at para 249 of its judgment.
403. To put the matter in terms of the principle set out at paragraph 203 of the Decision, in our view the above facts demonstrate (i) that, during the period of the infringement, Napp's prices in the community segment were significantly higher than would be expected in a competitive market; and (ii) that, during the period of the infringement, there was no significant competitive pressure to bring them down to competitive levels, nor was there likely to be over any reasonable time scale."
"the Ramsey pricing principle … states that it is economically efficient to recover a relatively larger part of common or joint costs from those customers whose demand is relatively more inelastic (i.e. less sensitive to price).": OFT Economic Discussion paper 6 (July 2003) (OFT 657).
Discriminatory pricing
"applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties, thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage"
"Discriminatory pricing can be described as the supply or purchase of units of goods or services at different prices which do not correspond with differentials in supply costs"
See also United Brands; Hoffmann-La Roche; 226/84 British Leyland v Commission [1986] ECR 3263.
"Price discrimination is not necessarily undesirable. It may permit the more efficient utilisation of resources and may be essential to the economic viability of the enterprise. For example, lower fares on railways at certain times of day or to certain classes of customer can contribute to the fuller utilisation of scheduled services by encouraging their use during otherwise slack periods and this may be the only way of running the system at all in the absence of an unacceptable level of public subsidy. Discriminatory pricing may also facilitate structural changes in the economy. For example, the discounts available to supermarkets were a major factor in their growth at the expense of smaller retail outlets. However, the changes facilitated may themselves lead to undesirable effects such as an unacceptable degree of concentration in the retail markets. It is also arguable that price discrimination may enhance competition. If firms were unable to discriminate by offering lower prices to certain customers they might go out of business, reducing the number of suppliers in the market. This is particularly true of suppliers of commodities which cannot be stored, such as transportation services. In short, in some circumstances price discrimination will strengthen the dominant firm's position or lead to inefficiencies but in others it will increase competition. Each instance will depend on its own facts. In the EC geographical price discrimination causes particular problems and the Court and the Commission have condemned discriminatory pricing in discount schemes and its use as an exclusionary tactic. An undertaking may not apply artificial price differences such as to place its customers at a disadvantage and to distort competition.
"BHB regarded broadcasters and information providers as being in an entirely separate category from bookmakers or distributors. Information providers … generate interest in British racing, as do broadcasters. Further, such users derive less value from British racing by having access to data, in contrast to, for example, bookmakers. Thus the fee charged to them is only a nominal sum, which is intended merely to give rise to the need for a written licence to be entered into containing the basic terms which BHB insists on being included."
Mr Smith confirmed that approach in his oral evidence at the trial.
The Government's proposals
"As regards the problems relating to the safety of consumers and therefore the reputation of the model, the solution can only be legislative. If there is a gap in the British system of type approval - the apparent lack of a right on the part of a manufacturer or any authority appointed to that effect to check that a conversion has been properly carried out after the issue of the certificate of conformity - the solution must be found in the adoption of appropriate laws or regulations, and not in a measure which by distorting the normal competition represented by prices of re-imported vehicles…amounts to depriving dealers and therefore private individuals of the possibility of purchasing vehicles at a lower price."
Decision